Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Chairman individualism and cost structure decisions

Chairman individualism and cost structure decisions CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 2022, VOL. 10, NO. 4, 503–527 https://doi.org/10.1080/21697213.2022.2143682 ARTICLE a b Wei Jiang and Yuan Sun a b Business School, Renmin University of China, Beijing, China; School of Management, Xiamen University, Xiamen, China ABSTRACT KEYWORDS Chairman individualism Taking a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) personal traits strategic cost China as a proxy for chairman individualism (collectivism), this management cost structure paper examines how such individualism affects firms’ cost structure decisions within a sample of Chinese listed firms. The results show that individualistic chairmen tend to choose a rigid cost structure. Further analysis shows that this relationship exists only in non-state -owned enterprises, when the board has a low level of indepen- dence, and when the firm has a low level of financial leverage. This paper contributes to the literature on firms' cost structure decisions in response to risk and on the effect of managerial individualism (collectivism) on corporate strategic cost management. Moreover, this paper provides implications for Chinese firms to realise the advantages of strategic cost management through managers' lea- dership roles and to achieve transformation and sustainable development. 1. Introduction Purchased materials and services account for an increasingly large proportion of firms’ product costs. Accordingly, managers often make strategic decisions about supply chain management. As supply chain management is becoming increasingly complex, strategic cost management, a form of deliberate decision-making, plays an important role in aligning the cost structure of a firm with the establishment and enactment of strategies and in improving the efficiency and effectiveness of value chain management (Aberdeen Group, 2005). Strategic cost management can be divided into two primary categories: structural and executional cost management (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a, 2009b). Structural cost management is a choice among alternative production functions that use different inputs or combinations thereof to meet a particular market demand (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a) ; here, cost structure is defined as a mix of variable inputs (i.e. variable costs) and fixed inputs (i.e. fixed costs). Hence, a flexible cost structure is CONTACT Yuan Sun Sunyuan_Echo@163.com School of Management, Xiamen University, No. 422, Siming South Road, Xiamen, Fujian 361005, China Paper accepted by Donghua Chen. Statistics show that in manufacturing industries, the value of purchased materials and services has grown from 20% to 56% of the selling price of finished goods over the past 50 years (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a)........ Executional cost management is concerned with whether a firm is on an efficient frontier for a given production function (i.e. whether a firm’s performance is profitable). This article has been republished with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article. © 2022 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/ licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. 504 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN characterised by a large proportion of variable costs and a small proportion of fixed costs (Banker et al., 2014; Kallapur & Eldenburg, 2005). Generally, a change in the cost structure implies significant and possibly irreversible adjustments in the organisational structure and business activities, which may increase a firm’s operational or financial risk. Accordingly, a growing stream of management accounting research focuses on the relationship between a firm’s risk and its cost structure decisions. For example, Kallapur and Eldenburg (2005) and Holzhacker, Krishnan and Mahlendorf (2015a, 2015b) document that hospitals with high demand uncertainty are more likely than other hospitals to increase their cost flexibility to reduce risk. Banker et al. (2014) use a sample of U.S. manufacturing firms to show that firms facing higher customer demand uncertainty tend to adopt a less flexible cost structure to reduce congestion costs. Chang et al. (2017) and Jiang et al. (2018) document an association between customer concentration and cost structure, but their results are not consistent. Using data from U.S. listed companies, Chang et al. (2017) find that customer concentra- tion is positively associated with cost elasticity, whereas Jiang et al. (2018) find the opposite result when analysing data from Chinese listed companies. Overall, the studies mentioned above focus on firms’ cost structure decisions in response to demand-side risk from the perspective of the supply chain. Although Aboody et al. (2018) document the impact of reductions in option-based compensation on managerial risk preferences and, in turn, firms’ cost structure decisions, few studies investigate the effects of managers’ personal traits related to risk or external incentive systems on firms’ cost structure decisions. Therefore, understanding how these personal traits of managers affect firms’ cost structure decisions may have important theoretical and practical implications. The literature on cross-cultural psychology suggests that culture influences individuals’ beliefs and preferences and thus has economic consequences (Alesina & Giuliano, 2015; Guiso et al., 2006). Culture is difficult to change and devalue, and it is generally con- sidered a ‘given’ trait that accompanies individuals throughout their lifespan and is embedded in their behaviours (Becker, 1996). Inspired by cross-cultural psychology, studies in accounting and finance show that managers’ cultural backgrounds, early experiences and family environments affect their personal traits and behaviours and thus affect their decisions on matters such as corporate finance, stock crashes and earn- ings forecasts (Bennedsen et al., 2007; Bertrand & Schoar, 2003; Cronqvist et al., 2012; Kim et al., 2016; Malmendier et al., 2011). However, few management accounting studies provide evidence of the association between managers’ personal traits and firms’ cost management from the perspective of cross-cultural psychology (Abernethy & Wallis, 2019). In this study, we examine the effect of one personal trait of chairmen, individualism, on firms’ cost structure decisions in China. Through their leadership role in a firm (Krause Cost structure and cost stickiness are related but distinct concepts. Both concepts can be classified as cost behaviour, and both represent the association between a firm’s costs and its sales revenue. However, they differ in that cost structure is characterised by a proportion of both variable and fixed costs (e.g. Banker et al., 2014), while cost stickiness measures the asymmetrical change in costs in response to increases or decreases in a firm’s sales revenues (e.g. Anderson et al., 2003). Several researchers examine the factors affecting cost stickiness in China, including Jiang et al. (2015), Liang et al. (2015), Mao et al. (2015), Jiang et al. (2016), Jiang et al. (2017), Liu et al. (2017), Wang & Gao (2017), Zhang et al. (2019), and Zhou et al. (2019). Culture can be defined as the customary beliefs and values transmitted in fairly unchanged forms between generations within ethnic, religious, and social groups (Guiso et al., 2006). CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 505 et al., 2016; Withers & Fitza, 2017), the chairman directly affects corporate strategy and contributes to major business decisions, such as a firm’s operational and financing policies (Jiang & Kim, 2015; Zhu et al., 2016). The ‘rice theory’ posits that an individualistic culture is more common in Northern than Southern China, whereas a collectivistic culture is more prevalent in Southern China due to historical differences in regional agricultural cultiva- tion and production (Talhelm et al., 2014). Accordingly, we adopt a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern China as a proxy for chairman individualism and find that compared with their collectivistic counterparts, individualistic chairmen tend to choose a less flexible cost structure, which is defined as a larger proportion of fixed costs and smaller proportion of variable costs. Moreover, we find that the negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced for state-owned enterprises (SOEs) than for non-SOEs, for firms whose boards of directors are more (vs. less) independent, and for firms with higher (vs. lower) financial leverage. Our study contributes to the literature in two primary ways. First, our study con- tributes to the growing literature on firms’ cost structure decisions in response to risk. Research in this area focuses primarily on demand-side risk, such as demand uncer- tainty and customer concentration, from the perspective of the supply chain (Kallapur & Eldenburg, 2005; Banker et al., 2014; Holzhacker et al., 2015a, 2015b; Chang et al., 2017; Jiang et al., 2018). Aboody et al. (2018) demonstrate that managers adjust firms’ cost structures in response to reductions in risk-taking incentives. In contrast, we show empirically that cost structure decisions are shaped by managers’ personal traits rather than by managerial incentives. We thus provide a potential avenue to explore the risk factors influencing firms’ cost management. Second, our study contributes to cross-cultural studies, especially in the area of consequences of personal individualism (collectivism). Research mainly focuses on the effects of managers’ individualism (collectivism) on financial accounting and corporate finance policies (Brochet et al., 2019; Chui et al., 2010; Han et al., 2010; Kanagaretnam et al., 2011, 2014). We extend this research to management account- ing by examining the association between chairman individualism and firms’ cost structure decisions. Country-level measures of culture (i.e. individualism vs. collecti- vism) may be subject to the confounding effects of institutional differences across countries in areas such as accounting rules, tax regulations and legal enforcement (Guiso et al., 2006). Consequently, researchers exploring culture and finance face the major challenge of measuring culture (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism) at the firm or individual level. Based on the rice theory (Talhelm et al., 2014), we use a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern China as the individual-level measure of chairman individualism to overcome the problems associated with a country-level measure of culture (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism), as China is ethnically and politically uni- fied. Although many studies show that managers’ overconfidence can affect firms’ risk-taking and operational decisions (Galasso & Simcoe, 2011; Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; Malmendier & Tate, 2008), we believe that a manager’s individualism (collecti- vism) is an exogenous trait that affects their tendency towards overconfidence (Hofstede, 2001) and thus affects firms’ operational decisions. 506 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN 2. Literature review and hypothesis development Research in the field of cross-cultural psychology suggests that the dichotomy of indivi- dualism and collectivism is one of the most significant (Hofstede, 1980; Hofstede, 2001) and fruitful dimensions in the area of cultural differences (Heine, 2008). Specifically, individualism is characterised by self-orientation, autonomy and achievement, and peo- ple from individualistic cultures are likely to prioritise individual goals (Fiske et al., 1998; Singelis et al., 1995). In contrast, collectivism emphasises self-sacrifice, harmony and cooperation, and people from collectivistic cultures tend to pursue group goals even at the expense of their individual goals (Carpenter, 2000; Kulkarni et al., 2010). Cross-country studies use the country-level individualism–collectivism index devel- oped by Hofstede (1980, 2001) and cross-country samples to investigate the effects of individualism and collectivism on investment and accounting decisions. For example, some studies examine the effects of investors’ individualism on stock price momentum and co-movement (Chui et al., 2010; Eun et al., 2015). Other studies investigate the effects of managers’ individualism on firms’ earnings management and information disclosure attributes (Brochet et al., 2019; Han et al., 2010). Using a cross-country sample of banks, Kanagaretnam et al. (2011) demonstrate that banks in individualistic countries are more likely than those in collectivistic countries to use earnings management to meet or beat earnings in the prior year and to smooth earnings. In a study of banks, Kanagaretnam et al. (2014) also document that individualistic culture is negatively associated with accounting conservatism but positively associated with risk-taking. Although these studies discussed above partly uncover the relationships between individualism and finance and account- ing policies, the findings are vulnerable to the confounding effects of cross-country institutional differences in areas such as accounting rules, tax regulations and legal enforcement. To alleviate this vulnerability, we use individual-level individualism (collec- tivism) to examine the effect of chairman individualism (collectivism) on firms’ cost structure decisions in a within-country setting. China provides an ideal within-country setting for an investigation of the effects of individualism and collectivism. Following Hofstede’s individualism–collectivism index (Hofstede, 1980, 2001), China generally has a collectivistic culture. However, this simple classification method does not consider regional cultural diversity in China, which covers a large geographic area and has a long history. The populations in geographic areas such as the Yellow River Basin and Yangtze River Basin are representatives of the distinctive cultural traits of Northern and Southern China, respectively. Despite acknowledgement of the differences in personal traits caused by cultural discrepancies between these regions of China, the cultural discrepancy between Northern and Southern China was first defined as the difference between collectivism and individualism in 2014, when Talhelm et al. (2014) proposed the rice theory. Fei (1985) shows that because Chinese traditional culture is rooted in agriculture, Chinese people tend to have a strong sense of affiliation with the land. Similarly, the rice theory proposed by Talhelm et al. (2014) notes that, from the perspective of irrigation, To address the concern of institutional differences across countries, studies increasingly examine the effects of cultural differences within a country. For example, Li et al. (2013) investigate the effect of a firm’s country of origin on capital structure in Chinese business evironment, while Nguyen et al. (2018) investigate the effect of CEOs’ cultural heritage on firms’ operational decisions in a U.S. sample. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 507 growing rice requires significant amounts of water, and coordination among neighbours is essential during the irrigation stage of rice farming. In contrast, wheat farming can be completed independently with very little help from neighbours because wheat demands minimum amount of water. Furthermore, rice farming is significantly more labour- intensive compared to wheat farming. Finally, harvesting rice requires more group effort than harvesting wheat. Due to these significant agricultural differences, people from the rice-farming regions have gradually developed collectivistic traits, whereas people from the wheat-farming areas have become individualistic over time. Across China, rice and wheat have been farmed primarily in southern and northern regions, respectively, for thousands of years, leading to long-term regional cultural traditions despite the aban- donment of farming by most people in modern Chinese society. As Talhelm et al. (2014) base their rice theory on evidence from a survey of 1,162 Han Chinese participants in six regions of China, we think that it is feasible to use the cultural differences between Northern and Southern China as a proxy for individualism vs. collectivism, given China’s ethnic and political unification. We therefore use this proxy to investigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions. We focus on chairman individualism because the chairman plays the most important leadership role in a Chinese firm. Chinese listed companies are usually controlled by large shareholders, who can appoint a chairman of the board of directors to protect their own interests. Accordingly, chairmen of Chinese firms have greater power to set corporate policies than their counterparts in the U.S. and the U.K. As the conveners and moderators of board meetings, chairmen also control the agendas and tone of the meetings and thus influence firms’ major strategic and business decisions (Jiang & Kim, 2015; Zhu et al., 2016). Therefore, this institutional background (i.e. the chairman’s leadership role in a Chinese firm) enables us to investigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions in China. Research in the field of cross-cultural psychology suggests that individuals’ behaviours in adulthood are shaped by their cultural backgrounds, early experiences and family environments (Shweder, 1991; Triandis, 2001). As these influences affect corporate man- agers’ behaviours (Malmendier et al., 2011), we propose that an individualistic (vs. a collectivistic) chairman is more willing to take risk in pursuit of self-orientation, personal achievement and autonomy (Fiske et al., 1998; Singelis et al., 1995). In such circumstances, an individualistic chairman is likely to underestimate or even ignore the operational risk and possible damage to other relevant stakeholders’ interest caused by an increase in operating leverage; consequently, the chairman is likely to choose a larger proportion of fixed costs in anticipation of a marginal cost reduction due to economies of scale. Furthermore, chairman individualism may also lead to overconfidence (Hofstede, 2001), and research shows that an overconfident chairman tends to overestimate the firm’s future cash flow and underestimate the risk associated with operational decisions (Galasso & Simcoe, 2011; Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; Malmendier & Tate, 2008). For example, data published by the National Bureau of Statistics of China indicate that in our sample period, the average rice production yield in Southern Chinese provinces was about 65% of the total grain yield, compared with only about 10% in Northern Chinese provinces. In China, people of Han Chinese ethnicity comprise more than 90% of the total population. In the most recent millennium, regions characterised by wheat and rice farming have been governed by the same dynasties, which alleviates concern about the omission of variables related to ethnicity and political factors in most cross-cultural studies of Eastern and Western countries. 508 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Therefore, an individualistic chairman may underestimate the operational risk caused by a larger proportion of fixed costs and choose a less flexible cost structure. Based on the above arguments, we posit our first hypothesis as follows: H1: Chairman individualism is negatively associated with flexibility of cost structure. China and Chinese SOEs are typical examples of a collectivistic culture. Given the political function of SOEs, the chairmen of these firms are more committed to achieving social goals, such as employee welfare and social stability, than to achieving individual goals (Chen et al., 2011; Ke et al., 2012). This commitment reduces their incentives to undertake a higher level of operational risk for the sake of self-fulfilment. In addition, the chairmen of SOEs are usually appointed by the government and have implicit political roles (Fan et al., 2007; Cao et al., 2019). These chairmen are more likely to fulfill their corporate and social duties under the pressure of political promotion and thus maintain their reputations, leading to a higher degree of operational risk aversion. Therefore, we expect the unique characteristics of SOEs to mitigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ high-risk operational decisions, such that individualistic chairmen of SOEs tend to choose a more flexible cost structure to decrease their firms’ operational risk. In contrast, non-SOEs are less influenced by the collectivistic tradition; accordingly, chairman individualism should significantly influence these firms’ operational decisions such as choosing a larger proportion of fixed costs. Based on the above arguments, we posit our second hypothesis as follows: H2: The negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced in SOEs than in non-SOEs. Compared with inside directors, independent outside directors are more alert to decision biases caused by chairmen’s personal traits. Practically, independent directors can correct these biases by proposing adjustments to compensation, personnel appoint- ments or the removal of chairmen (Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; Malmendier & Tate, 2005). Consistent with these observations, studies based on samples of Chinese listed compa- nies find that independent directors play a positive role in corporate governance through supervision and consulting (Chen & Xiang, 2017; Jiang et al., 2016; Liu et al., 2015; Ye et al., 2011). Therefore, individualistic chairmen’s risk-taking behaviours should be more heavily regulated when the firm’s board includes a higher (vs. lower) percentage of independent directors, and this regulation should motivate the chairmen to choose a more flexible cost structure. Based on the above arguments, we posit our third hypothesis as follows: H3: The negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced in firms whose boards of directors are more (vs. less) independent. According to the fundamental principle of corporate finance, corporate risk primarily include financial risk and operational risk, which are respectively characterised by high financial leverage and high operating leverage. As simultaneously high levels of financial and operating leverage generally cause an exponential increase in overall risk through the CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 509 multiplier effect, chairmen must balance these two types of leverage to control firms’ overall risk. Therefore, when a firm’s financial leverage is higher, an individualistic chair- man is strongly incentivised to choose a more flexible cost structure, i.e. lower operating leverage, to control the firm’s overall risk. Based on the above arguments, we posit our fourth hypothesis as follows: H4: The negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced when a firm’s financial leverage is higher (vs. lower). 3. Research design 3.1. Sample selection Our sample consists of Chinese listed companies during the 2003–2017 period. Chairmen’s native places of origin data, corporate financial data and corporate govern- ment data are obtained from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database. To construct our sample, we first exclude firms in the financial sector. Second, we exclude firm–year observations with missing financial data or information about firms’ ownership or chairmen’s native places of origin. Third, we exclude firms whose chairmen’s native places of origin are in Tibet, Inner Mongolia and Xinjiang, as these regions are typically inhabited by people of nomadic cultures, who are different from people of Han ethnicity and culture in many respects, including language and religion. Fourth, we exclude firms whose chairmen’s native places of origin are in Hong Kong, Macao and Taiwan, as these three regions differ from China's Mainland in ethnicity, politics, culture and religion. Finally, we exclude firm- year observations with debt-to-asset ratios greater than 1. The above exclusions result in a final sample of 12,511 firm–year observations. All of the variables are winsorised at the 1% and 99% levels to control for the potential impact of outliers. 3.2. Variable measurement of chairman individualism We use a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for personal individualism (collectivism). Individualism is a dummy variable that equals 1 if a chairman is from Northern China and 0 if they are from Southern China. Figure 1 shows the boundary between Northern and Southern China. In our sample, Northern China includes the provinces of Qinghai, Beijing, Ningxia, Jilin, Gansu, Shandong, Shanxi, Shaanxi, Hebei, Heilongjiang, Liaoning, Henan and Tianjin. Southern China includes the provinces of Shanghai, Jiangxi, Zhejiang, Guangdong, Fujian, Hunan, Hainan, Hubei, Sichuan, Chongqing, Jiangsu, Guangxi, Anhui, Guizhou and Yunnan. Only some firms disclose their chairman's native places of origin. Accordingly, the CSMAR database provides this information for around 50% of the chairmen of all Chinese listed companies during our sample period. 510 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Figure 1. The boundary of Northern and Southern China. We measure individualism (collectivism) at the individual level using a chairman’s native place of origin for the following reasons. First, compared with previous studies based on country-level cultural characteristics (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism), our approach mitigates the confounding effects of national or regional institutional differ - ences such as accounting rules, tax regulations and legal enforcement (Guiso et al., 2006). Second, the distinct north–south discrepancy (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism) that has arisen in China due to historical differences in agricultural cultivation has lasted for thousands of years. These cultural differences have had a steady and persistent influence on Chinese people (Talhelm et al., 2014). Third, culture is difficult to change and devalue; accordingly, it is considered a ‘given’ trait held by an individual (Guiso et al., 2006). Jiang et al. (2019) apply a measure of individual-level collectivism (individualism) that indicates whether a chairman’s native place of origin is in Southern (Northern) China to a sample of Chinese listed companies, and they document that the compensation gap in a firm run by a chairman from a collectivistic culture tends to be smaller than that of a firm run by a chairman from an individualistic culture. Fan et al. (2022) use the percentage of cultivated land in each province devoted to rice paddies as a proxy for collectivist culture in an analysis of the founders of Chinese private-sector firms and find that a collectivist culture has a significant effect on the ownership structure of a family firm. In addition, Liu et al. (2019) provide evidence that supports the ‘rice theory’ based on a large-scale survey of Chinese interviewees. We concede that China’s traditional agricultural culture has a weak influence on people in urban areas in modern society, but the measurement noise caused by the phenomenon will bias against finding any results in our analyses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 511 3.3. Model specification Our main hypothesis (H1) predicts a negative association between chairman individual- ism and flexibility of cost structure. Following the literature (Anderson et al., 2003; Banker et al., 2014; Chang et al., 2017), we measure flexibility of cost structure using cost elasticity, which we capture using the following log-linear model: � � � � � � COGS Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t log ¼ β þ β � log þ β � log � Individualism i;t 0 1 2 COGS Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � Ownership þ β � log � GDPG þ β � log � AI i;t i;t i;t 3 4 5 Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � EI þ β � log � Uncerntainty þ β � log � Size 6 i;t 7 i;t 8 i;t Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � Leverage þ β � log � Age þ β � log � Tenure i;t i;t i;t 9 10 11 Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � Gender þ β � log � Independent þ β � log � Duality i;t i;t i;t 12 13 14 Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 þ β � Individualism þ β � Ownership þ β � GDPG þ β � AI þ β � EI 15 i;t 16 i;t 17 i;t 18 i;t 19 i;t þ β � Uncerntainty þ β � Size þ β � Leverage þ β � Age þ β � Tenure 20 i;t 21 i;t 22 i;t 23 i;t 24 i;t X X þ β � Gender þ β � Independent þ β � Duality þ Firmþ Year þ ε i;t i;t i;t 25 26 27 COGS i;t where log½ � represents the log-change in the cost of goods sold (COGS) for firm COGS i;t 1 Sales i;t i from year t-1 to year t; log½ � represents the log-change in sales revenue for firm Sales i;t 1 i from year t-1 to year t; Individualism is the chairman individualism measure, as defined i,t above, for firm i in year t. We use the COGS in our main analyses because chairmen are usually involved in firms’ strategic and other major business decisions that affect operat- ing costs, such as investing in fixed assets and hiring employees; these costs are most likely included in the COGS rather than in selling, general and administrative (SG&A) expenses (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a, 2009b). The coefficient β captures the base cost elasticity when the values of Individualism 1 i,t and other control variables are zero. This coefficient reflects the percentage change in COGS per each 1% change in sales revenue (Anderson et al., 2003). A small value of β implies a weak association between changes in sales revenue and changes in COGS, indicating a less flexible cost structure. The coefficient β on the interaction term Sales i;t log½ �*Individualism captures the effect of chairman individualism on cost elasticity. i,t Sales i;t 1 A positive (negative) β indicates that chairman individualism increases (decreases) cost elasticity. Therefore, our main hypothesis (H1) predicts a negative β . Following the literature (Anderson et al., 2003; Banker et al., 2014; Chang et al., 2017), we include the following control variables in our regression models: firm ownership (Ownership), GDP growth (GDPG), asset intensity (AI), employee intensity (EI), demand uncertainty (Uncertainty), firm size (Size) and liability-to-asset ratio (Leverage). Furthermore, we include the chairman’s age (Age), tenure (Tenure) and gender (Gender), the independence of the board of directors (Independent) and whether a chairman holds the position of CEO (Duality) to account for the associations of chairman individualism with the chairman’s characteristics and corporate governance factors. In addition, we control for firm and year fixed effects to address concern about the endogeneity of chairman individualism (Adams & Ferreira, 2009; Firth et al., 2015). Table 1 provides the definitions of all of the variables. 512 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 1. Definitions of variables. Variables Definition COGS i;t log-change in Log-change in COGS for firm i from year t-1 to year t: log½ �. COGS i;t 1 COGS Sales i;t log-change in Log-change in Sales for firm i from year t-1 to year t: log½ �. Sales i;t 1 Sales Individualism Dummy variable equal to 1 if a chairman’s native place of origin is in Northern China and 0 otherwise. Ownership Dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise and 0 otherwise. GDPG Percentage growth in the gross domestic product (GDP) over the year. AI Asset intensity, calculated as the total assets/sales revenue. EI Employee intensity, calculated as the number of employees/sales revenue (units of 10,000 RMB). Sales i;t Uncertainty Demand uncertainty, calculated as the standard deviation of log½ � over the most recent three- Sales i;t 1 year period. Size Firm size, calculated as the natural logarithm of total assets. Leverage Firm leverage rate, calculated as the total liabilities/total assets. Age Chairman age, calculated as the natural logarithm of a chairman’s age (in years). Tenure Chairman tenure, calculated as the natural logarithm of a chairman’s tenure (in months). Gender Dummy variable equal to 1 if a chairman is male and 0 otherwise. Independent Independence of the board of directors, calculated as the number of independent directors/the total number of directors on the board. Duality Dummy variable equal to 1 if a chairman also holds a CEO position and 0 otherwise. 4. Empirical results 4.1. Descriptive statistics Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for the variables in our study. The average value of Individualism is 0.38, indicating that chairmen whose native places of origin are in Northern China account for about 38% of our sample observations. The average Ownership value is 0.51, indicating that SOEs account for around 51% of our sample observations. The average Leverage is 0.48. In addition, the average Age in our sample is approximately 52 years, and the average Tenure is 62 months. On average, male chairmen (Gender) account for 96% of our sample observations. Independent directors (Independent) account for 37% of all members of boards of directors, and 19% of chairmen hold CEO positions (Duality). Table 2. Descriptive statistics. Variables Mean MIN Median MAX STD log-change in COGS 0.15 −0.90 0.13 1.83 0.35 log-change in Sales 0.15 −0.80 0.13 1.71 0.33 Individualism 0.38 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.49 Ownership 0.51 0.00 1.00 1.00 0.50 GDPG 0.09 0.06 0.09 0.15 0.02 AI 2.49 0.38 1.85 4.18 2.17 EI 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.10 0.02 Uncertainty 0.25 0.01 0.16 1.98 0.31 Size 22.09 19.48 21.90 26.06 1.32 Leverage 0.48 0.06 0.49 0.90 0.20 Age (row value) 52.40 36.00 52.00 71.00 7.11 Tenure (row value, in month) 62.34 1.00 56.00 179.00 42.54 Gender 0.96 0.00 1.00 1.00 0.19 Independent 0.37 0.22 0.33 0.57 0.05 Duality 0.19 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.40 CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 513 4.2. Chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure 4.2.1. Test of H1 Table 3 reports the estimations for our regression model of the association between chairman individualism and cost elasticity. As shown in column (1), we find that β is significantly positive (β = 1.575, t = 10.54), indicating a positive association between the change in COGS and the change in sales revenue in Chinese listed companies. Consistent with H1, we find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.023, t = −2.34). The results suggest that an individualistic (vs. a collectivistic) chairman is more likely to take risk or be overconfident and consequently tends to choose a less flexible cost structure (i.e. a larger proportion of fixed costs). Following Talhelm et al. (2014), we create a ranked categorical measure of chairman individualism as follows. First, we use agriculture statistics during 1988, which are pub- lished by the National Bureau of Statistics of China, to calculate the ratio of cultivated land in each province used for wheat farming to that used for rice farming. As we intend to assess the crops grown historically in different regions, without the influence of advanced irrigation and mechanisation, we use cultivated land statistics for each pro- vince, rather than yield statistics. Second, we rank the ratios of cultivated land for wheat vs. rice farming and sort them into 10 groups: the group with the highest ratio is classified as 1, while the group with the lowest ratio is classified as 0.1, and other groups take values within the range of 0.1 to 1 according to their ranks. Third, we match chairmen in corresponding groups by province, such that more individualistic chairmen are placed in higher ranked groups. The results are presented in column (2) of Table 3. After using this alternative measure of chairman individualism, we find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.050, t = −2.79), consistent with the results in column (1). We also calculate the ratio of cultivated land in each province used for wheat farming to all land cultivated for crops and create ranked groups as described above. We obtain similar results that support H1, as shown in column (3) of Table 3. An alternative explanation pertaining to the effect of culture at individual level is that a chairman whose native place of origin is in Northern (Southern) China is likely to work in a firm located in Northern (Southern) China, such that the influence of regional-level culture remains steady. To rule out this alternative explanation, we re-examine the regression using a region fixed effect model. The results are presented in column (4) of Table 3. We find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.024, t = −2.71), consistent with our earlier findings, and thus our results remain unchanged. We also rerun our main regression model using data on chairmen’s birthplaces from the CSMAR database. Using the definition of Individualism provided in Section 3.2, we find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.023, t = −2.30), as shown in column (5) of Table 3. Taken together, these results suggest that our H1 is robust to a battery of alternative checks. Note that 1988 is the earliest year for which agriculture statistics are available from the National Bureau of Statistics of China. The sample size decreases to 12,494 observations after we delete 17 firm-year observations for chairmen whose birthplaces are in Tibet, Inner Mongolia or Xinjiang. 514 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 3. Regression results for H1. South-North region-fixed effect chairman’s (0–1) wheat/rice wheat/crops model birthplace logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Constant −0.444*** −0.455*** −0.451*** −0.095** −0.442*** (−3.70) (−3.78) (−3.75) (−2.12) (−3.68) logsales 1.575*** 1.584*** 1.589*** 1.474*** 1.575*** -10.54 -10.59 -10.63 -10.97 -10.53 Logsales*Individualism −0.023** −0.050*** −0.072*** −0.024*** −0.023** (−2.34) (−2.79) (−3.87) (−2.71) (−2.30) logsales*Ownership 0.011 0.01 0.011 0.005 0.011 -1.11 -0.99 -1.08 -0.53 -1.12 logsales*GDPG 0.129 0.129 0.135 0.166 0.125 -0.56 -0.55 -0.58 -0.79 -0.54 logsales*AI −0.006*** −0.006*** −0.006*** −0.004** −0.006*** (−2.92) (−3.01) (−3.07) (−2.04) (−2.92) logsales*EI −1.350*** −1.325*** −1.327*** −1.229*** −1.353*** (−4.24) (−4.16) (−4.17) (−4.27) (−4.24) logsales*Uncertainty 0.007 0.007 0.005 −0.007 0.007 -0.66 -0.65 -0.48 (−0.73) -0.65 logsales*Size −0.001 −0.001 −0.001 0 −0.001 (−0.33) (−0.22) (−0.14) -0.1 (−0.33) logsales*Leverage 0.111*** 0.109*** 0.107*** 0.084*** 0.111*** -4.75 -4.66 -4.6 -4.04 -4.75 logsales*Age −0.171*** −0.171*** −0.171*** −0.151*** −0.171*** (−5.15) (−5.14) (−5.14) (−5.04) (−5.14) logsales*Tenure 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.011*** 0.013*** -3.07 -3.04 -3.09 -2.92 -3.04 logsales*Gender 0.047** 0.047** 0.048** 0.044** 0.047** -2.52 -2.52 -2.53 -2.45 -2.52 logsales*Independent 0.02 0.023 0.021 0.059 0.02 -0.3 -0.34 -0.31 -0.97 -0.3 logsales*Duality 0.013 0.011 0.011 0.01 0.013 -0.96 -0.82 -0.83 -0.81 -0.95 Individualism 0.002 0.02 0.021 0.005 0.003 -0.31 -1.34 -1.34 -1.48 -0.31 Ownership 0 −0.000 −0.000 −0.001 0 -0.01 (−0.00) (−0.00) (−0.39) -0.01 GDPG 1.245*** 1.247*** 1.246*** - 1.242*** -4.01 -4.03 -4.03 - -4 AI −0.001 −0.001 −0.001 0 −0.001 (−0.50) (−0.50) (−0.48) -0.59 (−0.50) EI 0.349** 0.346** 0.347** 0.353*** 0.347** -2.54 -2.51 -2.52 -4.54 -2.52 Uncertainty −0.006 −0.006 −0.006 −0.003 −0.006 (−1.05) (−1.03) (−0.94) (−0.66) (−1.05) Size 0.016*** 0.016*** 0.016*** 0.002* 0.016*** -5.06 -5.02 -4.98 -1.9 -5.04 Leverage 0.013 0.014 0.014 −0.006 0.012 -0.99 -1.07 -1.12 (−0.83) -0.99 Age 0.001 0.002 0.001 0.011 0.001 -0.05 -0.09 -0.06 -1.11 -0.04 Tenure 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 -0.66 -0.66 -0.68 -0.42 -0.68 Gender −0.014 −0.013 −0.014 −0.003 −0.014 (−0.97) (−0.91) (−0.96) (−0.53) (−0.97) Independent −0.030 −0.031 −0.032 0.007 −0.031 (−0.89) (−0.91) (−0.93) -0.29 (−0.90) Duality −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 0.001 −0.004 (−0.79) (−0.73) (−0.73) -0.4 (−0.78) Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Region FE Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N 12,511 12,511 12,511 12,511 12,494 Adj. R 0.854 0.854 0.854 0.879 0.854 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 515 4.2.2. Robustness check Next, we conduct a change analysis. Specifically, we first choose a sample of firms whose chairmen were replaced and construct the variable ΔIndividualism, which equals 1 if a collectivistic chairman is replaced by an individualistic chairman, −1 if the reverse change occurs or 0 if replacement of the chairman does not lead to a change between individualism and collectivism. Second, following Irvine et al. (2016), we measure firm-specific cost elasticity (CE) by logðCOGS =COGS Þ= logðSales =Sales Þ and test whether a change in cost elas- i;t i;t 1 i;t i;t 1 ticity is associated with a change in chairman individualism. Third, we expect that the incoming chairman will take some time to adjust the firm’s cost structure; therefore, we regress the change in cost elasticity (∆CE ) on the lagged change in chairman t+1 individualism (∆Individualism ). The results are presented in Table 4. We find that the coefficient on the lagged change in chairman individualism is significantly negative, suggesting that an increase in individualism due to chairman change leads to a decrease in a firm’s cost elasticity. We re-examine our H1 using a sample of Chinese listed companies in the manufactur- ing industry, which account for over 60% of our full sample, as strategic cost management is especially important for manufacturing firms (Chang et al., 2017). The results are presented in Table 5, which demonstrates that our H1 holds for all of the analyses except that shown in column (5). The literature shows that chairmen play an important leadership role in board meetings, where they have the ultimate power to set the tone of meetings and thus directly affect firms’ strategic and major business decisions (Jiang & Kim, 2015; Zhu et al., 2016). Undeniably, CEOs also strongly influence firms’ strategic and major business decisions. Therefore, we use a CEO’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for individualism (collectivism) and examine the effect of CEO individualism on firms’ cost elasticity. Furthermore, we perform the same alter- native checks for CEO individualism as described for chairman individualism in Section 4.2.1. The results are shown in Table 6. We find that although β2 is still negative, the effect of CEO individualism on cost elasticity is less significantly negative than that of chairman individualism. The results suggest that individualistic CEOs have a smaller impact on firms’ cost structure decisions than individualistic chairmen do. 4.2.3. Tests of H2–H4 H2 predicts that the negative association between chairman individualism and flex - ibility of cost structure will be less pronounced in SOEs than in non-SOEs. Table 7 presents the regression results for H2. In the subsample analysis, columns (1) and (2) respectively show that β is significantly negative (β = −0.032, t = −1.87) for non- Our sample period includes 4,157 firm-year observations involving changes in chairmen but only 578 observations that disclose complete information about the chairmen’s native places of origin before and after the changes in chairmen. Finally, our sample size for the change model decreases to 499 observations after deleting firm-year observations with missing values for control variables. In the regression model, we also control for CEO age (Age), tenure (Tenure) and gender (Gender). 516 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 4. Change analysis. Variables ΔCE Constant −1.044 (−0.25) ΔIndividualism −1.480** (−2.15) ΔOwnership −2.496 (−1.46) ΔGDPG 3.73 -0.34 ΔAI −0.285 (−1.00) ΔEI −18.539 (−0.51) ΔUncertainty −1.602 (−0.99) ΔSize 0.259 -0.28 ΔLeverage −0.912 (−0.28) ΔAge −2.307 (−1.18) ΔTenure 0.085 -0.27 ΔGender −0.156 (−0.11) ΔIndependent −16.195** (−2.48) ΔDuality 0.72 -0.85 Firm FE Yes Year FE Yes N 499 Adj. R 0.115 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. SOEs but nonsignificant (β = 0.001, t = 0.10) for SOEs, which is consistent with H2. We further divide SOEs into those administrated by the central government and by local governments and find that β remains nonsignificant (β = 0.015, t = 0.85 and β = 0.000, t = 0.03, respectively), as shown in columns (3) and (4). The results suggest in SOEs, the collectivistic culture and political promotion pressure mitigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions. Therefore, individualistic chairmen of SOEs are likely to choose a more flexible cost structure, whereas individualistic chairmen of non-SOEs are likely to choose a less flexible cost structure because their firms are less influenced by collectivism. H3 predicts that the negative association between chairman individualism and flex - ibility of cost structure will be less pronounced in firms whose boards of directors are The results of a test of differences in coefficients between subsamples show that β is significantly different between SOEs and non-SOEs. In the following subsample difference tests for H3 and H4, which test the moderating effects of board independence and financial leverage, respectively, we obtain similar results, which are not described below. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 517 Table 5. Regression results for H1-Manufacturing industry sample. South-North region-fixed (0–1) wheat/rice wheat/crops effect model chairman’s birthplace logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Constant −0.680*** −0.705*** −0.704*** −0.092** −0.679*** (−5.38) (−5.56) (−5.57) (−1.97) (−5.38) logsales 1.694*** 1.727*** 1.736*** 1.674*** 1.690*** -10.49 -10.69 -10.76 -11.42 -10.46 Logsales*Individualism −0.020* −0.081*** −0.107*** −0.026*** −0.017 (−1.83) (−4.07) (−5.27) (−2.64) (−1.56) logsales*Ownership 0.009 0.009 0.01 0.003 0.008 -0.8 -0.82 -0.9 -0.27 -0.76 logsales*GDPG 0.088 0.062 0.078 −0.040 0.093 -0.33 -0.24 -0.29 (−0.16) -0.35 logsales*AI −0.018*** −0.018*** −0.018*** −0.013*** −0.018*** (−6.13) (−6.13) (−6.21) (−5.06) (−6.13) logsales*EI 0.629* 0.694* 0.675* 0.197 0.620* -1.68 -1.86 -1.81 -0.58 -1.66 logsales*Uncertainty 0.045*** 0.042*** 0.038*** 0.022* 0.045*** -3.35 -3.13 -2.9 -1.83 -3.38 logsales*Size −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 (−0.90) (−0.80) (−0.82) (−0.96) (−0.92) logsales*Leverage 0.047* 0.047* 0.043* 0.051** 0.047* -1.79 -1.78 -1.65 -2.13 -1.79 logsales*Age −0.189*** −0.189*** −0.187*** −0.171*** −0.187*** (−5.34) (−5.38) (−5.32) (−5.33) (−5.31) logsales*Tenure 0.020*** 0.020*** 0.021*** 0.015*** 0.020*** -3.93 -4.03 -4.12 -3.39 -3.92 logsales*Gender −0.010 −0.013 −0.014 −0.018 −0.010 (−0.35) (−0.48) (−0.50) (−0.68) (−0.36) logsales*Independent 0.126* 0.127* 0.120* 0.133* 0.125* -1.72 -1.73 -1.65 -1.93 -1.72 logsales*Duality 0.012 0.007 0.008 0.003 0.012 -0.83 -0.52 -0.56 -0.21 -0.84 Individualism 0.006 0.043** 0.050*** 0.007** 0.007 -0.72 -2.41 -2.84 -1.96 -0.83 Ownership 0.001 0 0 −0.002 0.001 -0.15 -0.02 -0.04 (−0.73) -0.14 GDPG 1.812*** 1.845*** 1.838*** - 1.811*** -5.59 -5.71 -5.7 - -5.59 AI 0.003* 0.003* 0.003* 0.001 0.003* -1.88 -1.92 -1.95 -0.84 -1.88 EI 0.327** 0.326** 0.337** 0.146 0.327** -2.05 -2.05 -2.12 -1.59 -2.05 Uncertainty −0.005 −0.004 −0.003 −0.013** −0.005 (−0.65) (−0.52) (−0.38) (−2.11) (−0.66) Size 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.004*** 0.021*** -6.15 -6.12 -6.13 -2.72 -6.15 Leverage 0.02 0.022* 0.023* 0.004 0.02 -1.56 -1.69 -1.76 -0.5 -1.56 Age 0.017 0.019 0.018 0.004 0.017 -0.8 -0.87 -0.81 -0.36 -0.78 Tenure 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.001 -0.48 -0.54 -0.6 -1.22 -0.48 Gender −0.021 −0.021 −0.022 0.006 −0.020 (−1.23) (−1.27) (−1.33) -0.82 (−1.22) Independent −0.040 −0.042 −0.042 0.002 −0.039 (−1.12) (−1.19) (−1.21) -0.08 (−1.11) Duality −0.001 −0.000 −0.000 0.001 −0.001 (−0.19) (−0.03) (−0.03) -0.14 (−0.21) Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Region FE Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N 7,545 7,545 7,545 7,545 7,539 Adj. R 0.882 0.882 0.882 0.901 0.882 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. 518 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN more (vs. less) independent. We divide the full sample into High_Indepen and Low_Indepen subsamples according to the yearly median value of Independent and examine the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost elasticity. Table 8 presents the regression results for H3. The results of the subsample analysis are presented in columns (1) and (2), which respectively show that β is nonsignificant (β = −0.012, t = −0.74) for the High_Indepen subsample but significantly negative (β = −0.047, t = −3.62) for the Low_Indepen subsample, which is consistent with H3. The results imply in firms with more independent directors, individualistic chairmen’s risk-taking behaviours attract attention from the independent directors, who can impose restrictions on firms’ cost structure decisions. H4 predicts that the negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure will be less pronounced when firms’ financial leverage is higher (vs. lower). We divide the full sample into High_Lev and Low_Lev subsamples according to the yearly median value of Leverage and examine the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost elasticity. Table 9 presents the regression results for H4. Columns (1) and (2) show that β is nonsignificant (β = −0.006, t = −0.51) for the High_Lev subsample but significantly negative (β = −0.032, t = −1.85) for the Low_Lev sample, which is consistent with H4. The results suggest in a firm with higher financial leverage, an individualistic chairman is highly incentivised to control the firm’s overall risk by choosing a more flexible cost structure (i.e. lower operating leverage). 4.2.4. Additional tests We perform the following tests to further validate our results. First, we delete firm– year observations wherein chairmen also hold CEO positions. Second, we construct an alternative continuous variable of chairman individualism which is the percentage of cultivated land used for rice farming in the province that corresponds to a chairman’s native place of origin, and rerun our regressions. Third, we exclude firm- year observations wherein the chairmen’s native places of origin are in Sichuan, Chongqing, Anhui, Hubei, Jiangsu and Guizhou because these provinces lie along the boundary between Northern and Southern China. Fourth, we control for the chairman’s education level using the following scores: 1 = associate’s degree, 2 = bachelor’s degree, 3 = master’s degree and 4 = doctor’s degree. As the CSMAR database does not contain complete information on all chairmen’s education levels, we assume chairmen with lower levels of education are less willing to disclose this information; therefore, we set 0 = missing education level. Last, we control for a chairman’s compensation. As not all compensation is paid by the listed company, we control for both the payment of chairman’s compensation by the listed company and the amount of cash compensation. Our results remain robust after conducting these additional tests. The dual position of chairman and CEO may increase a chairman’s overconfidence and thus substitute for the effect of chairman individualism (collectivism). Nevertheless, we do not find a significantly negative association between chairman individualism and cost elasticity when a chairman holds a CEO position. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 519 Table 6. Regression results for H1-CEO Sample. South-North region-fixed (0–1) wheat/rice wheat/crops effect model chairman’s birthplace logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Constant −0.447** −0.462** −0.473** −0.156** −0.447** (−2.35) (−2.43) (−2.49) (−2.33) (−2.35) logsales 1.079*** 1.082*** 1.082*** 0.974*** 1.072*** -4.62 -4.63 -4.63 -4.8 -4.58 Logsales*Individualism −0.028* −0.025 −0.037 −0.026* −0.028* (−1.80) (−0.91) (−1.37) (−1.91) (−1.82) logsales*Ownership −0.024 −0.027* −0.026* −0.023* −0.024 (−1.58) (−1.75) (−1.71) (−1.72) (−1.59) logsales*GDPG 0.549 0.568* 0.567* 0.362 0.559* -1.62 -1.68 -1.67 -1.2 -1.65 logsales*AI −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.002 −0.004 (−1.24) (−1.22) (−1.25) (−1.03) (−1.30) logsales*EI −2.201*** −2.226*** −2.216*** −1.845*** −2.188*** (−5.29) (−5.34) (−5.32) (−5.12) (−5.24) logsales*Uncertainty −0.012 −0.010 −0.011 −0.002 −0.012 (−0.71) (−0.58) (−0.65) (−0.13) (−0.72) logsales*Size −0.014** −0.014** −0.014** −0.008* −0.014** (−2.56) (−2.51) (−2.47) (−1.68) (−2.53) logsales*Leverage 0.146*** 0.144*** 0.143*** 0.114*** 0.147*** -4.24 -4.19 -4.15 -3.84 -4.26 logsales*Age 0.003 0.001 0.002 0.012 0.004 -0.06 -0.03 -0.05 -0.27 -0.07 logsales*Tenure 0.004 0.005 0.004 0.007 0.005 -0.7 -0.73 -0.69 -1.3 -0.8 logsales*Gender 0.046* 0.048* 0.048* 0.026 0.045* -1.77 -1.87 -1.86 -1.15 -1.75 logsales*Independent 0.355*** 0.352*** 0.352*** 0.266*** 0.356*** -3.36 -3.33 -3.33 -2.87 -3.37 logsales*Duality 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 -0.38 -0.34 -0.34 -0.44 -0.36 Individualism 0.032*** 0.061*** 0.069*** 0.003 0.033*** -2.64 -2.78 -2.98 -0.6 -2.7 Ownership −0.022 −0.021 −0.021 −0.003 −0.023 (−1.52) (−1.42) (−1.44) (−0.63) (−1.53) GDPG 0.798 0.785 0.8 - 0.849* -1.64 -1.61 -1.64 - -1.74 AI 0.003* 0.003* 0.002* 0.001 0.003** -1.88 -1.75 -1.7 -1.17 -2.03 EI 0.545*** 0.560*** 0.563*** 0.505*** 0.526*** -2.74 -2.82 -2.83 -4.9 -2.64 Uncertainty 0.005 0.005 0.005 −0.015** 0.006 -0.52 -0.52 -0.52 (−2.00) -0.61 Size 0.015*** 0.014*** 0.015*** 0.005*** 0.015*** -2.94 -2.79 -2.86 -2.63 -2.91 Leverage −0.019 −0.018 −0.016 −0.017 −0.019 (−0.94) (−0.87) (−0.78) (−1.63) (−0.94) Age 0.002 0.005 0.004 0.011 0.001 -0.05 -0.15 -0.12 -0.72 -0.04 Tenure 0.001 0.001 0.001 0 0.001 -0.31 -0.31 -0.35 -0.12 -0.27 Gender 0.035* 0.035* 0.035 0.008 0.035* -1.66 -1.69 -1.64 -0.94 -1.66 Independent −0.030 −0.034 −0.033 0.01 −0.029 (−0.57) (−0.64) (−0.61) -0.29 (−0.54) Duality 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.002 -0.24 -0.26 -0.27 -0.29 -0.26 Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Region FE Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N 6,800 6,800 6,800 6,800 6,785 Adj. R 0.826 0.826 0.826 0.864 0.826 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. 520 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 7. Regression results for H2. Non-SOEs SOEs Central SOEs Local SOEs logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant −0.193 −0.339** −0.494** −0.230 (−0.91) (−2.53) (−2.28) (−1.36) logsales 1.049*** 1.591*** 1.872*** 1.523*** (4.32) (8.87) (6.64) (6.69) Logsales*Individualism −0.032* 0.001 0.015 0.000 (−1.87) (0.10) (0.85) (0.03) logsales*GDPG 0.471 −0.040 0.239 −0.176 (1.21) (−0.16) (0.59) (−0.56) logsales*AI −0.015*** 0.010*** −0.011** 0.012*** (−4.60) (4.32) (−2.20) (4.44) logsales*EI −0.608 −1.795*** 0.592 −2.104*** (−1.15) (−4.96) (0.84) (−4.82) logsales*Uncertainty 0.008 0.027** 0.014 0.021 (0.48) (2.02) (0.58) (1.34) logsales*Size 0.019*** −0.022*** −0.016** −0.020*** (2.70) (−5.12) (−2.39) (−3.58) Logsales*Leverage 0.141*** 0.079*** 0.084* 0.064* (3.85) (2.83) (1.68) (1.86) logsales*Age −0.178*** −0.031 −0.137* −0.016 (−3.62) (−0.70) (−1.93) (−0.30) logsales*Tenure 0.019** 0.001 −0.012 0.004 (2.44) (0.30) (−1.43) (0.67) logsales*Gender 0.055** 0.024 0.097 0.014 (2.19) (0.75) (1.48) (0.37) logsales*Independent 0.157 −0.111 −0.321** −0.089 (1.42) (−1.52) (−2.40) (−1.02) logsales*Duality 0.047** −0.034* 0.044 −0.048** (2.48) (−1.74) (1.25) (−2.03) Individualism 0.000 −0.000 0.004 −0.008 (0.02) (−0.05) (0.46) (−0.69) GDPG 1.813*** 0.542* 0.437 0.422 (2.86) (1.70) (0.81) (1.07) AI −0.001 0.001 0.004 0.002 (−0.45) (0.93) (1.31) (1.13) EI 0.094 0.358** −0.296 0.454** (0.41) (2.15) (−0.92) (2.29) Uncertainty −0.008 −0.001 0.010 0.001 (−0.79) (−0.16) (0.80) (0.16) Size 0.012** 0.011*** 0.016*** 0.006 (2.14) (2.86) (2.81) (1.19) Leverage 0.015 0.004 −0.049** 0.016 (0.72) (0.28) (−2.05) (0.90) Age −0.024 0.004 0.012 0.006 (−0.66) (0.18) (0.33) (0.18) Tenure 0.002 0.002 −0.000 0.004 (0.50) (1.29) (−0.01) (1.59) Gender −0.052* −0.001 0.031 −0.011 (−1.75) (−0.09) (1.01) (−0.67) Independent −0.176*** 0.074** 0.059 0.090** (−2.80) (2.13) (0.98) (2.12) Duality −0.004 −0.007 −0.025** −0.003 (−0.53) (−1.10) (−2.12) (−0.37) Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes N 6,162 6,349 1,694 4,655 Adj. R 0.823 0.901 0.924 0.894 p-value for diff . of β 0.086* - - Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 521 Table 8. Regression results for H3. High_Indepen Low_Indepen logCOGS (1) (2) Constant −0.204 −0.715*** (−0.93) (−4.47) logsales 1.412*** 1.601*** (5.59) (8.47) Logsales*Individualism −0.012 −0.047*** (−0.74) (−3.62) logsales*Ownership −0.014 0.038*** (−0.81) (2.96) logsales*GDPG −0.274 0.434 (−0.68) (1.50) logsales*AI −0.011*** −0.003 (−3.32) (−1.07) logsales*EI −2.060*** −1.367*** (−3.57) (−3.42) logsales*Uncertainty 0.018 0.013 (0.97) (0.89) logsales*Size −0.015** −0.002 (−2.19) (−0.41) logsales*Leverage 0.218*** 0.093*** (5.55) (3.10) logsales*Age −0.063 −0.177*** (−1.14) (−4.09) logsales*Tenure 0.018** 0.005 (2.53) (0.87) logsales*Gender 0.082** 0.064*** (2.30) (2.87) logsales*Duality 0.076*** −0.009 (3.44) (−0.48) Individualism 0.002 0.006 (0.16) (0.50) Ownership 0.005 −0.005 (0.25) (−0.41) GDPG 1.955*** 1.418*** (3.23) (3.59) AI −0.001 −0.003** (−0.30) (−2.11) EI 0.995*** 0.277 (3.62) (1.59) Uncertainty −0.018* −0.008 (−1.69) (−0.95) Size 0.007 0.022*** (1.25) (5.21) Leverage 0.038* 0.014 (1.68) (0.87) Age −0.039 0.036 (−1.05) (1.21) Tenure 0.006* −0.000 (1.67) (−0.04) Gender −0.002 −0.019 (−0.07) (−1.04) Duality −0.012 0.005 (−1.28) (0.66) Firm FE Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes N 5,447 7,064 Adj. R 0.819 0.863 p-value for diff . of β 0.050** Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. 522 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 9. Regression results for H4. High_Lev Low_Lev logCOGS (1) (2) Constant −0.271* −0.452** (−1.75) (−2.02) logsales 1.478*** 1.676*** (8.23) (6.22) Logsales*Individualism −0.006 −0.032* (−0.51) (−1.85) logsales*Ownership 0.011 0.014 (0.94) (0.77) logsales*GDPG 0.345 0.128 (1.21) (0.32) logsales*AI 0.006** −0.022*** (2.56) (−6.13) logsales*EI −1.246*** −0.852 (−3.12) (−1.58) logsales*Uncertainty 0.006 0.006 (0.49) (0.29) logsales*Size 0.000 −0.006 (0.03) (−0.84) logsales*Age −0.128*** −0.172*** (−3.10) (−3.01) logsales*Tenure 0.007 0.005 (1.40) (0.57) logsales*Gender −0.012 0.133*** (−0.51) (4.21) logsales*Independent −0.004 0.117 (−0.06) (0.90) logsales*Duality −0.018 0.070*** (−1.03) (3.16) Individualism 0.010 −0.013 (1.05) (−0.77) Ownership 0.020* 0.017 (1.84) (1.02) GDPG 0.820** 0.755 (2.04) (1.39) AI 0.001 −0.003 (0.88) (−1.29) EI 0.200 0.676*** (1.12) (2.72) Uncertainty −0.002 −0.015 (−0.22) (−1.31) Size 0.006 0.019*** (1.63) (3.04) Age 0.002 0.006 (0.06) (0.17) Tenure 0.000 0.006 (0.16) (1.54) Gender 0.007 −0.030 (0.44) (−0.97) Independent 0.052 −0.086 (1.20) (−1.49) Duality 0.001 −0.018** (0.15) (−2.08) Firm FE Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes N 6,253 6,258 Adj. R 0.897 0.772 p-value for diff . of β 0.091* Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 523 5. Conclusion The increasing complexity of supply chain management may expose firms to substantial risk. Accordingly, a growing body of literature in the field of management accounting investigates firms’ cost structure decisions in response to risk. However, the literature primarily focuses on demand-side risk such as demand uncertainty and customer concentration. Few studies pay attention to risk related to managers’ personal traits and firms’ incentive systems (Aboody et al., 2018). Investigation of firms’ cost structure decisions from the perspective of manager-side risk has important theoretical and practical implications. Accordingly, we examine the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions in a sample of Chinese listed companies, using a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for indivi- dualism (collectivism). Our results show that individualistic chairmen tend to choose a less flexible cost structure. Furthermore, the negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced for SOEs (vs. non-SOEs), firms with more (vs. less) independent boards of directors and firms with higher (vs. lower) financial leverage. Our study presents both theoretical contributions and practical implications. It contri- butes to the growing literature on firms’ cost structure decisions in response to risk and extends the literature on the effects of individual-level individualism (collectivism) on corporate finance and financial accounting decisions to the study of management account- ing decisions, especially strategic cost management. Our study also provides insights into firms’ strategic cost management practices. It changes the paradigm wherein most knowl- edge on structural cost management comes from fields outside accounting, and it provides practical guidance for firms’ managers, accountants and the government. In particular, our findings may assist the Ministry of Finance in improving and implementing the ‘Fundamental Guidelines for Management Accounting’. Overall, our study provides empiri- cal evidence on the importance of managers’ leadership on Chinese firms’ strategic cost management, which can help firms to achieve transformation and sustainable development. Our study has two main limitations. First, regarding the challenge of measuring culture (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism) at the firm or individual level, although this paper tries to use a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for chair- man individualism (collectivism), we still cannot fully rule out the confounding effects of the discrepancy between Northern and Southern China. Future studies can explore more direct and accurate measures. Second, our paper only examines the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions from the perspective of structural cost management, future research could also investigate how chairman individualism affects firms’ executional cost management, such as corporate strategy implementation and performance. Disclosure statement No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s). 524 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN References Aberdeen Group. (2005). Center-Led procurement-organizing resources and technology for sustained supply value. Boston. Abernethy, M.A., & Wallis, M. (2019). Critique on the “manager effects” research and implications for management accounting research. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 31(1), 3–40. https://doi.org/10.2308/jmar-52030 Aboody, D., Levi, S., & Weiss, D. (2018). Managerial incentives, options, and cost-structure choices. Review of Accounting Studies, 23(2), 422–451. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-017-9432-0 Adams, R.B., & Ferreira, D. (2009). Women in the boardroom and their impact on governance and performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 94(2), 291–309. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco. 2008.10.007 Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2015). Culture and institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4), 898–944. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.53.4.898 Anderson, M.C., Banker, R.D., & Janakiraman, S.N. (2003). Are selling, general, and administrative costs “sticky”? Journal of Accounting Research, 41(1), 47–63. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X. Anderson, S.W., & Dekker, H.C. (2009a). Strategic cost management in supply chains, part 1: Structural cost management. Accounting Horizons, 23(2), 201–220. https://doi.org/10.2308/acch. 2009.23.2.201 Anderson, S.W., & Dekker, H.C. (2009b). Strategic cost management in supply chains, part 2: Executional cost management. Accounting Horizons, 23(3), 289–305. https://doi.org/10.2308/ acch.2009.23.3.289 Banker, R.D., Byzalov, D., & Plehn-Dujowich, J.M. (2014). Demand uncertainty and cost behavior. The Accounting Review, 89(3), 839–865. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50661 Becker, G. (1996). Preferences and values. Harvard University Press. Bennedsen, M., Nielsen, K.M., Pérez-González, F., & Wolfenzon, D. (2007). Inside the family firm: The role of families in succession decisions and performance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (2), 647–691. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.122.2.647 Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with style: The effect of managers on firm policies. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1169–1208. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552775 Brochet, F., Miller, G.S., Naranjo, P., & Yu, G. (2019). Managers’ cultural background and disclosure attributes. The Accounting Review, 94(3), 57–86. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-52290 Cao, X., Lemmon, M., Pan, X., Qian, M., & Tian, G. (2019). Political promotion, CEO incentives, and the relationship between pay and performance. Management Science, 65(7), 2947–2965. https://doi. org/10.1287/mnsc.2017.2966 Carpenter, S. (2000). Effects of cultural tightness and collectivism on self-concept and causal attributions. Cross-Cultural Research, 34(1), 38–56. https://doi.org/10.1177/106939710003400103 Chang, H., Hall, C.M., & Paz, M. (2017). Customer concentration and cost structure. Working paper, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?Abstract_id=2482777 . Chen, J., Ezzamel, M., & Cai, Z. (2011). Managerial power theory, tournament theory, and executive pay in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(4), 1176–1199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin. 2011.04.008 Chen, D., & Xiang, J. (2017). Is it reasonable for independent directors to be re-elected for only six years? Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Management World, (5), 144–157. (In Chinese). https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2017.05.013 Chui, A.C., Titman, S., & Wei, K.J. (2010). Individualism and momentum around the world. The Journal of Finance, 65(1), 361–392. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01532.x Cronqvist, H., Makhija, A.K., & Yonker, S.E. (2012). Behavioral consistency in corporate finance: CEO personal and corporate leverage. Journal of Financial Economics, 103(1), 20–40. https://doi.org/10. 1016/j.jfineco.2011.08.005 Eun, C.S., Wang, L., & Xiao, S.C. (2015). Culture and R2. Journal of Financial Economics, 115(2), 283–303. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.09.003 CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 525 Fan, J.P., Gu, Q.K., & Yu, X. (2022). Collectivist cultures and the emergence of family firms, The Journal of Law and Economics, 65(S1), S293–S325. forthcoming. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3839978 . Fan, J.P., Wong, T.J., & Zhang, T. (2007). Politically connected CEOs, corporate governance, and Post- IPO performance of China’s newly partially privatized firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 84(2), 330–357. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2006.03.008 Fei, X. (1985). From the Soil - The Foundations of Chinese Society. SDX Joint Publishing Company. Firth, M., Leung, T.Y., Rui, O.M., & Na, C. (2015). Relative pay and its effects on firm efficiency in a transitional economy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 110, 59–77. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.jebo.2014.12.001 Fiske, A.P., Kitayama, S., Markus, H.R., & Nisbett, R.E. (1998). The cultural matrix of social psychology. McGraw-Hill. Galasso, A., & Simcoe, T.S. (2011). CEO overconfidence and innovation. Management Science, 57(8), 1469–1484. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1374 Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 23–48. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.20.2.23 Han, S., Kang, T., Salter, S., & Yoo, Y.K. (2010). A cross-country study on the effects of national culture on earnings management. Journal of International Business Studies, 41(1), 123–141. https://doi. org/10.1057/jibs.2008.78 Hayward, M.L., & Hambrick, D.C. (1997). Explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions: Evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(1), 103–127. https://doi.org/10. 2307/2393810 Heine, S.J. (2008). Cultural psychology. W.W. Norton & Company. Hofstede, G. (1980). Culture’s consequences. Sage Publications. Hofstede, G. (2001). Culture’s consequences: Comparing values, behaviors, institutions and organiza- tions across nations. Sage Publications. Holzhacker, M., Krishnan, R., & Mahlendorf, M.D. (2015a). The impact of changes in regulation on cost behavior. Contemporary Accounting Research, 32(2), 534–566. https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846. Holzhacker, M., Krishnan, R., & Mahlendorf, M.D. (2015b). Unraveling the black box of cost behavior: An empirical investigation of risk drivers, managerial resource procurement, and cost elasticity. The Accounting Review, 90(6), 2305–2335. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-51092 Irvine, P.J., Park, S.S., & Yıldızhan, Ç. (2016). Customer-Base Concentration, Profitability, and the Relationship Life Cycle. The Accounting Review, 91(3), 883–906. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr- Jiang, W., Di, L., & Yao, W. (2017). Customer concentration and firm cost stickiness: Evidence from Chinese listed companies in manufacturing industry. Journal of Financial Research, (9), 192–206. https://kns.cnki.net Jiang, W., Hu, Y., & Zeng, Y. (2015). Financial constraints and cost stickiness: Evidence from Chinese industrial firms. Journal of Financial Research, (10), 133–147. https://kns.cnki.net Jiang, F., & Kim, K.A. (2015). Corporate governance in China: A modern perspective. Journal of Corporate Finance, 32, 190–216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.10.010 Jiang, W., Lin, B., Liu, Y., & Xu, Y. (2019). Chairperson collectivism and the compensation gap between managers and employees: Evidence from China. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 27(4), 261–282. https://doi.org/10.1111/corg.12278 Jiang, W., Sun, Y., & Hu, Y. (2018). Customer concentration and cost structure decisions: Empirical evidence from Chinese Relation-oriented business environment. Accounting Research, (11), 70–76. https://kns.cnki.net Jiang, W., Wan, H., & Zhao, S. (2016). Reputation concerns of independent directors: Evidence from individual director voting. The Review of Financial Studies, 29(3), 655–696. https://doi.org/10.1093/ rfs/hhv125 Jiang, W., Yao, W., & Hu, Y. (2016). The enforcement of the Minimum Wage Policy in China and firm cost stickiness. China Journal of Accounting Studies, 4(3), 339–355. https://doi.org/10.1080/ 21697213.2016.1218631 526 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Kallapur, S., & Eldenburg, L. (2005). Uncertainty, real options, and cost behavior: Evidence from Washington state hospitals. Journal of Accounting Research, 43(5), 735–752. https://doi.org/10. 1111/j.1475-679X.2005.00188.x Kanagaretnam, K., Lim, C.Y., & Lobo, G.J. (2011). Effects of national culture on earnings quality of banks. Journal of International Business Studies, 42(6), 853–874. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2011. Kanagaretnam, K., Lim, C.Y., & Lobo, G.J. (2014). Influence of national culture on accounting conservatism and risk-taking in the banking industry. The Accounting Review, 89(3), 1115–1149. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50682 Ke, B., Rui, O., & Yu, W. (2012). Hong Kong stock listing and the sensitivity of managerial compensa- tion to firm performance in state-controlled Chinese firms. Review of Accounting Studies, 17(1), 166–188. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-011-9169-0 Kim, J.B., Wang, Z., & Zhang, L. (2016). CEO overconfidence and stock price crash risk. Contemporary Accounting Research, 33(4), 1720–1749. https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846.12217 Krause, R., Semadeni, M., & Withers, M.C. (2016). That special someone: When the board views its chair as a resource. Strategic Management Journal, 37(9), 1990–2002. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj. Kulkarni, S.P., Hudson, T., Ramamoorthy, N., Marchev, A., Georgieva-Kondakova, P., & Gorskov, V. (2010). Dimensions of individualism-collectivism: A comparative study of five cultures. Current Issues of Business & Law, 5(1), 93–109. https://doi.org/10.5200/1822-9530.2010.03 Liang, S., Chen, D., & Hu, X. (2015). External auditor types and the cost stickiness of listed companies. Accounting Research, (2), 79–86. https://kns.cnki.net Li, K., Griffin, D., Yue, H., & Zhao, L. (2013). How does culture influence corporate risk-taking? Journal of Corporate Finance, 23, 1–22. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2013.07.008 Liu, C., Li, S., & Sun, L. (2015). Do independent directors have the consulting function? An empirical study on the function of independent directors in strange land. Management World, (3), 124–136. (In Chinese). https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2015.03.012 Liu, S.S., Morris, M.W., Talhelm, T., & Yang, Q. (2019). Ingroup vigilance in collectivistic cultures. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 116(29), 14538–14546. https://doi.org/10.1073/ pnas.1817588116 Liu, H., Qi, Y., & Wang, H. (2017). On the cost stickiness difference between companies with different layers in pyramidal business group. Accounting Research, (7), 82–88. https://kns.cnki. net Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2005). CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. The Journal of Finance, 60(6), 2661–2700. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2011.01685.x Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2008). Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market’s reaction. Journal of Financial Economics, 89(1), 20–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2007.07. Malmendier, U., Tate, G., & Yan, J. (2011). Overconfidence and early-life experiences: The effect of managerial traits on corporate financial policies. The Journal of Finance, 66(5), 1687–1733. https:// doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2011.01685.x Mao, H., Li, Z., & Cheng, J. (2015). The effect of non-economic factors on asymmetric cost behavior: Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Naikai Management Review, (6), 136–145. https://kns. cnki.net Nguyen, D.D., Hagendorff, J., & Eshraghi, A. (2018). Does a CEO’s cultural heritage affect performance under competitive pressure? The Review of Financial Studies, 31(1), 97–141. https://doi.org/10. 1093/rfs/hhx046 Shweder, R.A. (1991). Thinking through cultures: Expeditions in cultural psychology. Harvard University Press. Singelis, T.M., Triandis, H.C., Bhawuk, D.P., & Gelfand, M.J. (1995). Horizontal and vertical dimensions of individualism and collectivism: A theoretical and measurement refinement. Cross-Cultural Research, 29(3), 240–275. https://doi.org/10.1177/106939719502900302 CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 527 Talhelm, T., Zhang, X., Oishi, S., Shimin, C., Duan, D., Lan, X., & Kitayama, S. (2014). Large-scale psychological differences within China explained by rice versus wheat agriculture. Science, 344 (6184), 603–608. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1246850 Triandis, H.C. (2001). Individualism-collectivism and personality. Journal of Personality, 69(6), 907–924. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6494.696169 Wang, X., & Gao, K. (2017). Customer relationship and cost stickiness: Hold-up or cooperation. Naikai Management Review, (1), 132–142. https://kns.cnki.net Withers, M.C., & Fitza, M.A. (2017). Do board chairs matter? The influence of board chairs on firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 38(6), 1343–1355. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2587 Ye, K., Zhu, J., Lu, Z., & Zhang, R. (2011). The Independence of independent directors: Evidence from board voting behavior. Economic Research Journal, (1), 126–139. https://kns.cnki.net Zhang, L., Li, J., Zhang, H., & Wang, H. (2019). Can managerial ability restrain company’s cost stickiness? Accounting Research, (3), 71–77. https://kns.cnki.net Zhou, L., Liu, H., & Zhang, H. (2019). How do former CEO directors affect corporate resource adjustment? Journal of Financial Research, (2), 169–187. https://kns.cnki.net Zhu, J., Ye, K., Tucker, J.W., & Chan, K.J.C. (2016). Board hierarchy, independent directors, and firm value: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 41, 262–279. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. jcorpfin.2016.09.009 http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png China Journal of Accounting Studies Taylor & Francis

Chairman individualism and cost structure decisions

China Journal of Accounting Studies , Volume 10 (4): 25 – Oct 2, 2022

Chairman individualism and cost structure decisions

Abstract

Taking a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for chairman individualism (collectivism), this paper examines how such individualism affects firms’ cost structure decisions within a sample of Chinese listed firms. The results show that individualistic chairmen tend to choose a rigid cost structure. Further analysis shows that this relationship exists only in non-state-owned enterprises, when the board has a low level of independence, and when...
Loading next page...
 
/lp/taylor-francis/chairman-individualism-and-cost-structure-decisions-ZdTzqdqzvQ
Publisher
Taylor & Francis
Copyright
© 2022 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group.
ISSN
2169-7221
eISSN
2169-7213
DOI
10.1080/21697213.2022.2143682
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 2022, VOL. 10, NO. 4, 503–527 https://doi.org/10.1080/21697213.2022.2143682 ARTICLE a b Wei Jiang and Yuan Sun a b Business School, Renmin University of China, Beijing, China; School of Management, Xiamen University, Xiamen, China ABSTRACT KEYWORDS Chairman individualism Taking a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) personal traits strategic cost China as a proxy for chairman individualism (collectivism), this management cost structure paper examines how such individualism affects firms’ cost structure decisions within a sample of Chinese listed firms. The results show that individualistic chairmen tend to choose a rigid cost structure. Further analysis shows that this relationship exists only in non-state -owned enterprises, when the board has a low level of indepen- dence, and when the firm has a low level of financial leverage. This paper contributes to the literature on firms' cost structure decisions in response to risk and on the effect of managerial individualism (collectivism) on corporate strategic cost management. Moreover, this paper provides implications for Chinese firms to realise the advantages of strategic cost management through managers' lea- dership roles and to achieve transformation and sustainable development. 1. Introduction Purchased materials and services account for an increasingly large proportion of firms’ product costs. Accordingly, managers often make strategic decisions about supply chain management. As supply chain management is becoming increasingly complex, strategic cost management, a form of deliberate decision-making, plays an important role in aligning the cost structure of a firm with the establishment and enactment of strategies and in improving the efficiency and effectiveness of value chain management (Aberdeen Group, 2005). Strategic cost management can be divided into two primary categories: structural and executional cost management (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a, 2009b). Structural cost management is a choice among alternative production functions that use different inputs or combinations thereof to meet a particular market demand (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a) ; here, cost structure is defined as a mix of variable inputs (i.e. variable costs) and fixed inputs (i.e. fixed costs). Hence, a flexible cost structure is CONTACT Yuan Sun Sunyuan_Echo@163.com School of Management, Xiamen University, No. 422, Siming South Road, Xiamen, Fujian 361005, China Paper accepted by Donghua Chen. Statistics show that in manufacturing industries, the value of purchased materials and services has grown from 20% to 56% of the selling price of finished goods over the past 50 years (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a)........ Executional cost management is concerned with whether a firm is on an efficient frontier for a given production function (i.e. whether a firm’s performance is profitable). This article has been republished with minor changes. These changes do not impact the academic content of the article. © 2022 The Author(s). Published by Informa UK Limited, trading as Taylor & Francis Group. This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (http://creativecommons.org/ licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. 504 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN characterised by a large proportion of variable costs and a small proportion of fixed costs (Banker et al., 2014; Kallapur & Eldenburg, 2005). Generally, a change in the cost structure implies significant and possibly irreversible adjustments in the organisational structure and business activities, which may increase a firm’s operational or financial risk. Accordingly, a growing stream of management accounting research focuses on the relationship between a firm’s risk and its cost structure decisions. For example, Kallapur and Eldenburg (2005) and Holzhacker, Krishnan and Mahlendorf (2015a, 2015b) document that hospitals with high demand uncertainty are more likely than other hospitals to increase their cost flexibility to reduce risk. Banker et al. (2014) use a sample of U.S. manufacturing firms to show that firms facing higher customer demand uncertainty tend to adopt a less flexible cost structure to reduce congestion costs. Chang et al. (2017) and Jiang et al. (2018) document an association between customer concentration and cost structure, but their results are not consistent. Using data from U.S. listed companies, Chang et al. (2017) find that customer concentra- tion is positively associated with cost elasticity, whereas Jiang et al. (2018) find the opposite result when analysing data from Chinese listed companies. Overall, the studies mentioned above focus on firms’ cost structure decisions in response to demand-side risk from the perspective of the supply chain. Although Aboody et al. (2018) document the impact of reductions in option-based compensation on managerial risk preferences and, in turn, firms’ cost structure decisions, few studies investigate the effects of managers’ personal traits related to risk or external incentive systems on firms’ cost structure decisions. Therefore, understanding how these personal traits of managers affect firms’ cost structure decisions may have important theoretical and practical implications. The literature on cross-cultural psychology suggests that culture influences individuals’ beliefs and preferences and thus has economic consequences (Alesina & Giuliano, 2015; Guiso et al., 2006). Culture is difficult to change and devalue, and it is generally con- sidered a ‘given’ trait that accompanies individuals throughout their lifespan and is embedded in their behaviours (Becker, 1996). Inspired by cross-cultural psychology, studies in accounting and finance show that managers’ cultural backgrounds, early experiences and family environments affect their personal traits and behaviours and thus affect their decisions on matters such as corporate finance, stock crashes and earn- ings forecasts (Bennedsen et al., 2007; Bertrand & Schoar, 2003; Cronqvist et al., 2012; Kim et al., 2016; Malmendier et al., 2011). However, few management accounting studies provide evidence of the association between managers’ personal traits and firms’ cost management from the perspective of cross-cultural psychology (Abernethy & Wallis, 2019). In this study, we examine the effect of one personal trait of chairmen, individualism, on firms’ cost structure decisions in China. Through their leadership role in a firm (Krause Cost structure and cost stickiness are related but distinct concepts. Both concepts can be classified as cost behaviour, and both represent the association between a firm’s costs and its sales revenue. However, they differ in that cost structure is characterised by a proportion of both variable and fixed costs (e.g. Banker et al., 2014), while cost stickiness measures the asymmetrical change in costs in response to increases or decreases in a firm’s sales revenues (e.g. Anderson et al., 2003). Several researchers examine the factors affecting cost stickiness in China, including Jiang et al. (2015), Liang et al. (2015), Mao et al. (2015), Jiang et al. (2016), Jiang et al. (2017), Liu et al. (2017), Wang & Gao (2017), Zhang et al. (2019), and Zhou et al. (2019). Culture can be defined as the customary beliefs and values transmitted in fairly unchanged forms between generations within ethnic, religious, and social groups (Guiso et al., 2006). CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 505 et al., 2016; Withers & Fitza, 2017), the chairman directly affects corporate strategy and contributes to major business decisions, such as a firm’s operational and financing policies (Jiang & Kim, 2015; Zhu et al., 2016). The ‘rice theory’ posits that an individualistic culture is more common in Northern than Southern China, whereas a collectivistic culture is more prevalent in Southern China due to historical differences in regional agricultural cultiva- tion and production (Talhelm et al., 2014). Accordingly, we adopt a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern China as a proxy for chairman individualism and find that compared with their collectivistic counterparts, individualistic chairmen tend to choose a less flexible cost structure, which is defined as a larger proportion of fixed costs and smaller proportion of variable costs. Moreover, we find that the negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced for state-owned enterprises (SOEs) than for non-SOEs, for firms whose boards of directors are more (vs. less) independent, and for firms with higher (vs. lower) financial leverage. Our study contributes to the literature in two primary ways. First, our study con- tributes to the growing literature on firms’ cost structure decisions in response to risk. Research in this area focuses primarily on demand-side risk, such as demand uncer- tainty and customer concentration, from the perspective of the supply chain (Kallapur & Eldenburg, 2005; Banker et al., 2014; Holzhacker et al., 2015a, 2015b; Chang et al., 2017; Jiang et al., 2018). Aboody et al. (2018) demonstrate that managers adjust firms’ cost structures in response to reductions in risk-taking incentives. In contrast, we show empirically that cost structure decisions are shaped by managers’ personal traits rather than by managerial incentives. We thus provide a potential avenue to explore the risk factors influencing firms’ cost management. Second, our study contributes to cross-cultural studies, especially in the area of consequences of personal individualism (collectivism). Research mainly focuses on the effects of managers’ individualism (collectivism) on financial accounting and corporate finance policies (Brochet et al., 2019; Chui et al., 2010; Han et al., 2010; Kanagaretnam et al., 2011, 2014). We extend this research to management account- ing by examining the association between chairman individualism and firms’ cost structure decisions. Country-level measures of culture (i.e. individualism vs. collecti- vism) may be subject to the confounding effects of institutional differences across countries in areas such as accounting rules, tax regulations and legal enforcement (Guiso et al., 2006). Consequently, researchers exploring culture and finance face the major challenge of measuring culture (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism) at the firm or individual level. Based on the rice theory (Talhelm et al., 2014), we use a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern China as the individual-level measure of chairman individualism to overcome the problems associated with a country-level measure of culture (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism), as China is ethnically and politically uni- fied. Although many studies show that managers’ overconfidence can affect firms’ risk-taking and operational decisions (Galasso & Simcoe, 2011; Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; Malmendier & Tate, 2008), we believe that a manager’s individualism (collecti- vism) is an exogenous trait that affects their tendency towards overconfidence (Hofstede, 2001) and thus affects firms’ operational decisions. 506 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN 2. Literature review and hypothesis development Research in the field of cross-cultural psychology suggests that the dichotomy of indivi- dualism and collectivism is one of the most significant (Hofstede, 1980; Hofstede, 2001) and fruitful dimensions in the area of cultural differences (Heine, 2008). Specifically, individualism is characterised by self-orientation, autonomy and achievement, and peo- ple from individualistic cultures are likely to prioritise individual goals (Fiske et al., 1998; Singelis et al., 1995). In contrast, collectivism emphasises self-sacrifice, harmony and cooperation, and people from collectivistic cultures tend to pursue group goals even at the expense of their individual goals (Carpenter, 2000; Kulkarni et al., 2010). Cross-country studies use the country-level individualism–collectivism index devel- oped by Hofstede (1980, 2001) and cross-country samples to investigate the effects of individualism and collectivism on investment and accounting decisions. For example, some studies examine the effects of investors’ individualism on stock price momentum and co-movement (Chui et al., 2010; Eun et al., 2015). Other studies investigate the effects of managers’ individualism on firms’ earnings management and information disclosure attributes (Brochet et al., 2019; Han et al., 2010). Using a cross-country sample of banks, Kanagaretnam et al. (2011) demonstrate that banks in individualistic countries are more likely than those in collectivistic countries to use earnings management to meet or beat earnings in the prior year and to smooth earnings. In a study of banks, Kanagaretnam et al. (2014) also document that individualistic culture is negatively associated with accounting conservatism but positively associated with risk-taking. Although these studies discussed above partly uncover the relationships between individualism and finance and account- ing policies, the findings are vulnerable to the confounding effects of cross-country institutional differences in areas such as accounting rules, tax regulations and legal enforcement. To alleviate this vulnerability, we use individual-level individualism (collec- tivism) to examine the effect of chairman individualism (collectivism) on firms’ cost structure decisions in a within-country setting. China provides an ideal within-country setting for an investigation of the effects of individualism and collectivism. Following Hofstede’s individualism–collectivism index (Hofstede, 1980, 2001), China generally has a collectivistic culture. However, this simple classification method does not consider regional cultural diversity in China, which covers a large geographic area and has a long history. The populations in geographic areas such as the Yellow River Basin and Yangtze River Basin are representatives of the distinctive cultural traits of Northern and Southern China, respectively. Despite acknowledgement of the differences in personal traits caused by cultural discrepancies between these regions of China, the cultural discrepancy between Northern and Southern China was first defined as the difference between collectivism and individualism in 2014, when Talhelm et al. (2014) proposed the rice theory. Fei (1985) shows that because Chinese traditional culture is rooted in agriculture, Chinese people tend to have a strong sense of affiliation with the land. Similarly, the rice theory proposed by Talhelm et al. (2014) notes that, from the perspective of irrigation, To address the concern of institutional differences across countries, studies increasingly examine the effects of cultural differences within a country. For example, Li et al. (2013) investigate the effect of a firm’s country of origin on capital structure in Chinese business evironment, while Nguyen et al. (2018) investigate the effect of CEOs’ cultural heritage on firms’ operational decisions in a U.S. sample. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 507 growing rice requires significant amounts of water, and coordination among neighbours is essential during the irrigation stage of rice farming. In contrast, wheat farming can be completed independently with very little help from neighbours because wheat demands minimum amount of water. Furthermore, rice farming is significantly more labour- intensive compared to wheat farming. Finally, harvesting rice requires more group effort than harvesting wheat. Due to these significant agricultural differences, people from the rice-farming regions have gradually developed collectivistic traits, whereas people from the wheat-farming areas have become individualistic over time. Across China, rice and wheat have been farmed primarily in southern and northern regions, respectively, for thousands of years, leading to long-term regional cultural traditions despite the aban- donment of farming by most people in modern Chinese society. As Talhelm et al. (2014) base their rice theory on evidence from a survey of 1,162 Han Chinese participants in six regions of China, we think that it is feasible to use the cultural differences between Northern and Southern China as a proxy for individualism vs. collectivism, given China’s ethnic and political unification. We therefore use this proxy to investigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions. We focus on chairman individualism because the chairman plays the most important leadership role in a Chinese firm. Chinese listed companies are usually controlled by large shareholders, who can appoint a chairman of the board of directors to protect their own interests. Accordingly, chairmen of Chinese firms have greater power to set corporate policies than their counterparts in the U.S. and the U.K. As the conveners and moderators of board meetings, chairmen also control the agendas and tone of the meetings and thus influence firms’ major strategic and business decisions (Jiang & Kim, 2015; Zhu et al., 2016). Therefore, this institutional background (i.e. the chairman’s leadership role in a Chinese firm) enables us to investigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions in China. Research in the field of cross-cultural psychology suggests that individuals’ behaviours in adulthood are shaped by their cultural backgrounds, early experiences and family environments (Shweder, 1991; Triandis, 2001). As these influences affect corporate man- agers’ behaviours (Malmendier et al., 2011), we propose that an individualistic (vs. a collectivistic) chairman is more willing to take risk in pursuit of self-orientation, personal achievement and autonomy (Fiske et al., 1998; Singelis et al., 1995). In such circumstances, an individualistic chairman is likely to underestimate or even ignore the operational risk and possible damage to other relevant stakeholders’ interest caused by an increase in operating leverage; consequently, the chairman is likely to choose a larger proportion of fixed costs in anticipation of a marginal cost reduction due to economies of scale. Furthermore, chairman individualism may also lead to overconfidence (Hofstede, 2001), and research shows that an overconfident chairman tends to overestimate the firm’s future cash flow and underestimate the risk associated with operational decisions (Galasso & Simcoe, 2011; Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; Malmendier & Tate, 2008). For example, data published by the National Bureau of Statistics of China indicate that in our sample period, the average rice production yield in Southern Chinese provinces was about 65% of the total grain yield, compared with only about 10% in Northern Chinese provinces. In China, people of Han Chinese ethnicity comprise more than 90% of the total population. In the most recent millennium, regions characterised by wheat and rice farming have been governed by the same dynasties, which alleviates concern about the omission of variables related to ethnicity and political factors in most cross-cultural studies of Eastern and Western countries. 508 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Therefore, an individualistic chairman may underestimate the operational risk caused by a larger proportion of fixed costs and choose a less flexible cost structure. Based on the above arguments, we posit our first hypothesis as follows: H1: Chairman individualism is negatively associated with flexibility of cost structure. China and Chinese SOEs are typical examples of a collectivistic culture. Given the political function of SOEs, the chairmen of these firms are more committed to achieving social goals, such as employee welfare and social stability, than to achieving individual goals (Chen et al., 2011; Ke et al., 2012). This commitment reduces their incentives to undertake a higher level of operational risk for the sake of self-fulfilment. In addition, the chairmen of SOEs are usually appointed by the government and have implicit political roles (Fan et al., 2007; Cao et al., 2019). These chairmen are more likely to fulfill their corporate and social duties under the pressure of political promotion and thus maintain their reputations, leading to a higher degree of operational risk aversion. Therefore, we expect the unique characteristics of SOEs to mitigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ high-risk operational decisions, such that individualistic chairmen of SOEs tend to choose a more flexible cost structure to decrease their firms’ operational risk. In contrast, non-SOEs are less influenced by the collectivistic tradition; accordingly, chairman individualism should significantly influence these firms’ operational decisions such as choosing a larger proportion of fixed costs. Based on the above arguments, we posit our second hypothesis as follows: H2: The negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced in SOEs than in non-SOEs. Compared with inside directors, independent outside directors are more alert to decision biases caused by chairmen’s personal traits. Practically, independent directors can correct these biases by proposing adjustments to compensation, personnel appoint- ments or the removal of chairmen (Hayward & Hambrick, 1997; Malmendier & Tate, 2005). Consistent with these observations, studies based on samples of Chinese listed compa- nies find that independent directors play a positive role in corporate governance through supervision and consulting (Chen & Xiang, 2017; Jiang et al., 2016; Liu et al., 2015; Ye et al., 2011). Therefore, individualistic chairmen’s risk-taking behaviours should be more heavily regulated when the firm’s board includes a higher (vs. lower) percentage of independent directors, and this regulation should motivate the chairmen to choose a more flexible cost structure. Based on the above arguments, we posit our third hypothesis as follows: H3: The negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced in firms whose boards of directors are more (vs. less) independent. According to the fundamental principle of corporate finance, corporate risk primarily include financial risk and operational risk, which are respectively characterised by high financial leverage and high operating leverage. As simultaneously high levels of financial and operating leverage generally cause an exponential increase in overall risk through the CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 509 multiplier effect, chairmen must balance these two types of leverage to control firms’ overall risk. Therefore, when a firm’s financial leverage is higher, an individualistic chair- man is strongly incentivised to choose a more flexible cost structure, i.e. lower operating leverage, to control the firm’s overall risk. Based on the above arguments, we posit our fourth hypothesis as follows: H4: The negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced when a firm’s financial leverage is higher (vs. lower). 3. Research design 3.1. Sample selection Our sample consists of Chinese listed companies during the 2003–2017 period. Chairmen’s native places of origin data, corporate financial data and corporate govern- ment data are obtained from the China Stock Market and Accounting Research (CSMAR) database. To construct our sample, we first exclude firms in the financial sector. Second, we exclude firm–year observations with missing financial data or information about firms’ ownership or chairmen’s native places of origin. Third, we exclude firms whose chairmen’s native places of origin are in Tibet, Inner Mongolia and Xinjiang, as these regions are typically inhabited by people of nomadic cultures, who are different from people of Han ethnicity and culture in many respects, including language and religion. Fourth, we exclude firms whose chairmen’s native places of origin are in Hong Kong, Macao and Taiwan, as these three regions differ from China's Mainland in ethnicity, politics, culture and religion. Finally, we exclude firm- year observations with debt-to-asset ratios greater than 1. The above exclusions result in a final sample of 12,511 firm–year observations. All of the variables are winsorised at the 1% and 99% levels to control for the potential impact of outliers. 3.2. Variable measurement of chairman individualism We use a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for personal individualism (collectivism). Individualism is a dummy variable that equals 1 if a chairman is from Northern China and 0 if they are from Southern China. Figure 1 shows the boundary between Northern and Southern China. In our sample, Northern China includes the provinces of Qinghai, Beijing, Ningxia, Jilin, Gansu, Shandong, Shanxi, Shaanxi, Hebei, Heilongjiang, Liaoning, Henan and Tianjin. Southern China includes the provinces of Shanghai, Jiangxi, Zhejiang, Guangdong, Fujian, Hunan, Hainan, Hubei, Sichuan, Chongqing, Jiangsu, Guangxi, Anhui, Guizhou and Yunnan. Only some firms disclose their chairman's native places of origin. Accordingly, the CSMAR database provides this information for around 50% of the chairmen of all Chinese listed companies during our sample period. 510 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Figure 1. The boundary of Northern and Southern China. We measure individualism (collectivism) at the individual level using a chairman’s native place of origin for the following reasons. First, compared with previous studies based on country-level cultural characteristics (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism), our approach mitigates the confounding effects of national or regional institutional differ - ences such as accounting rules, tax regulations and legal enforcement (Guiso et al., 2006). Second, the distinct north–south discrepancy (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism) that has arisen in China due to historical differences in agricultural cultivation has lasted for thousands of years. These cultural differences have had a steady and persistent influence on Chinese people (Talhelm et al., 2014). Third, culture is difficult to change and devalue; accordingly, it is considered a ‘given’ trait held by an individual (Guiso et al., 2006). Jiang et al. (2019) apply a measure of individual-level collectivism (individualism) that indicates whether a chairman’s native place of origin is in Southern (Northern) China to a sample of Chinese listed companies, and they document that the compensation gap in a firm run by a chairman from a collectivistic culture tends to be smaller than that of a firm run by a chairman from an individualistic culture. Fan et al. (2022) use the percentage of cultivated land in each province devoted to rice paddies as a proxy for collectivist culture in an analysis of the founders of Chinese private-sector firms and find that a collectivist culture has a significant effect on the ownership structure of a family firm. In addition, Liu et al. (2019) provide evidence that supports the ‘rice theory’ based on a large-scale survey of Chinese interviewees. We concede that China’s traditional agricultural culture has a weak influence on people in urban areas in modern society, but the measurement noise caused by the phenomenon will bias against finding any results in our analyses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 511 3.3. Model specification Our main hypothesis (H1) predicts a negative association between chairman individual- ism and flexibility of cost structure. Following the literature (Anderson et al., 2003; Banker et al., 2014; Chang et al., 2017), we measure flexibility of cost structure using cost elasticity, which we capture using the following log-linear model: � � � � � � COGS Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t log ¼ β þ β � log þ β � log � Individualism i;t 0 1 2 COGS Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � Ownership þ β � log � GDPG þ β � log � AI i;t i;t i;t 3 4 5 Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � EI þ β � log � Uncerntainty þ β � log � Size 6 i;t 7 i;t 8 i;t Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � Leverage þ β � log � Age þ β � log � Tenure i;t i;t i;t 9 10 11 Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 � � � � � � Sales Sales Sales i;t i;t i;t þ β � log � Gender þ β � log � Independent þ β � log � Duality i;t i;t i;t 12 13 14 Sales Sales Sales i;t 1 i;t 1 i;t 1 þ β � Individualism þ β � Ownership þ β � GDPG þ β � AI þ β � EI 15 i;t 16 i;t 17 i;t 18 i;t 19 i;t þ β � Uncerntainty þ β � Size þ β � Leverage þ β � Age þ β � Tenure 20 i;t 21 i;t 22 i;t 23 i;t 24 i;t X X þ β � Gender þ β � Independent þ β � Duality þ Firmþ Year þ ε i;t i;t i;t 25 26 27 COGS i;t where log½ � represents the log-change in the cost of goods sold (COGS) for firm COGS i;t 1 Sales i;t i from year t-1 to year t; log½ � represents the log-change in sales revenue for firm Sales i;t 1 i from year t-1 to year t; Individualism is the chairman individualism measure, as defined i,t above, for firm i in year t. We use the COGS in our main analyses because chairmen are usually involved in firms’ strategic and other major business decisions that affect operat- ing costs, such as investing in fixed assets and hiring employees; these costs are most likely included in the COGS rather than in selling, general and administrative (SG&A) expenses (Anderson & Dekker, 2009a, 2009b). The coefficient β captures the base cost elasticity when the values of Individualism 1 i,t and other control variables are zero. This coefficient reflects the percentage change in COGS per each 1% change in sales revenue (Anderson et al., 2003). A small value of β implies a weak association between changes in sales revenue and changes in COGS, indicating a less flexible cost structure. The coefficient β on the interaction term Sales i;t log½ �*Individualism captures the effect of chairman individualism on cost elasticity. i,t Sales i;t 1 A positive (negative) β indicates that chairman individualism increases (decreases) cost elasticity. Therefore, our main hypothesis (H1) predicts a negative β . Following the literature (Anderson et al., 2003; Banker et al., 2014; Chang et al., 2017), we include the following control variables in our regression models: firm ownership (Ownership), GDP growth (GDPG), asset intensity (AI), employee intensity (EI), demand uncertainty (Uncertainty), firm size (Size) and liability-to-asset ratio (Leverage). Furthermore, we include the chairman’s age (Age), tenure (Tenure) and gender (Gender), the independence of the board of directors (Independent) and whether a chairman holds the position of CEO (Duality) to account for the associations of chairman individualism with the chairman’s characteristics and corporate governance factors. In addition, we control for firm and year fixed effects to address concern about the endogeneity of chairman individualism (Adams & Ferreira, 2009; Firth et al., 2015). Table 1 provides the definitions of all of the variables. 512 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 1. Definitions of variables. Variables Definition COGS i;t log-change in Log-change in COGS for firm i from year t-1 to year t: log½ �. COGS i;t 1 COGS Sales i;t log-change in Log-change in Sales for firm i from year t-1 to year t: log½ �. Sales i;t 1 Sales Individualism Dummy variable equal to 1 if a chairman’s native place of origin is in Northern China and 0 otherwise. Ownership Dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm is a state-owned enterprise and 0 otherwise. GDPG Percentage growth in the gross domestic product (GDP) over the year. AI Asset intensity, calculated as the total assets/sales revenue. EI Employee intensity, calculated as the number of employees/sales revenue (units of 10,000 RMB). Sales i;t Uncertainty Demand uncertainty, calculated as the standard deviation of log½ � over the most recent three- Sales i;t 1 year period. Size Firm size, calculated as the natural logarithm of total assets. Leverage Firm leverage rate, calculated as the total liabilities/total assets. Age Chairman age, calculated as the natural logarithm of a chairman’s age (in years). Tenure Chairman tenure, calculated as the natural logarithm of a chairman’s tenure (in months). Gender Dummy variable equal to 1 if a chairman is male and 0 otherwise. Independent Independence of the board of directors, calculated as the number of independent directors/the total number of directors on the board. Duality Dummy variable equal to 1 if a chairman also holds a CEO position and 0 otherwise. 4. Empirical results 4.1. Descriptive statistics Table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for the variables in our study. The average value of Individualism is 0.38, indicating that chairmen whose native places of origin are in Northern China account for about 38% of our sample observations. The average Ownership value is 0.51, indicating that SOEs account for around 51% of our sample observations. The average Leverage is 0.48. In addition, the average Age in our sample is approximately 52 years, and the average Tenure is 62 months. On average, male chairmen (Gender) account for 96% of our sample observations. Independent directors (Independent) account for 37% of all members of boards of directors, and 19% of chairmen hold CEO positions (Duality). Table 2. Descriptive statistics. Variables Mean MIN Median MAX STD log-change in COGS 0.15 −0.90 0.13 1.83 0.35 log-change in Sales 0.15 −0.80 0.13 1.71 0.33 Individualism 0.38 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.49 Ownership 0.51 0.00 1.00 1.00 0.50 GDPG 0.09 0.06 0.09 0.15 0.02 AI 2.49 0.38 1.85 4.18 2.17 EI 0.02 0.00 0.01 0.10 0.02 Uncertainty 0.25 0.01 0.16 1.98 0.31 Size 22.09 19.48 21.90 26.06 1.32 Leverage 0.48 0.06 0.49 0.90 0.20 Age (row value) 52.40 36.00 52.00 71.00 7.11 Tenure (row value, in month) 62.34 1.00 56.00 179.00 42.54 Gender 0.96 0.00 1.00 1.00 0.19 Independent 0.37 0.22 0.33 0.57 0.05 Duality 0.19 0.00 0.00 1.00 0.40 CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 513 4.2. Chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure 4.2.1. Test of H1 Table 3 reports the estimations for our regression model of the association between chairman individualism and cost elasticity. As shown in column (1), we find that β is significantly positive (β = 1.575, t = 10.54), indicating a positive association between the change in COGS and the change in sales revenue in Chinese listed companies. Consistent with H1, we find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.023, t = −2.34). The results suggest that an individualistic (vs. a collectivistic) chairman is more likely to take risk or be overconfident and consequently tends to choose a less flexible cost structure (i.e. a larger proportion of fixed costs). Following Talhelm et al. (2014), we create a ranked categorical measure of chairman individualism as follows. First, we use agriculture statistics during 1988, which are pub- lished by the National Bureau of Statistics of China, to calculate the ratio of cultivated land in each province used for wheat farming to that used for rice farming. As we intend to assess the crops grown historically in different regions, without the influence of advanced irrigation and mechanisation, we use cultivated land statistics for each pro- vince, rather than yield statistics. Second, we rank the ratios of cultivated land for wheat vs. rice farming and sort them into 10 groups: the group with the highest ratio is classified as 1, while the group with the lowest ratio is classified as 0.1, and other groups take values within the range of 0.1 to 1 according to their ranks. Third, we match chairmen in corresponding groups by province, such that more individualistic chairmen are placed in higher ranked groups. The results are presented in column (2) of Table 3. After using this alternative measure of chairman individualism, we find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.050, t = −2.79), consistent with the results in column (1). We also calculate the ratio of cultivated land in each province used for wheat farming to all land cultivated for crops and create ranked groups as described above. We obtain similar results that support H1, as shown in column (3) of Table 3. An alternative explanation pertaining to the effect of culture at individual level is that a chairman whose native place of origin is in Northern (Southern) China is likely to work in a firm located in Northern (Southern) China, such that the influence of regional-level culture remains steady. To rule out this alternative explanation, we re-examine the regression using a region fixed effect model. The results are presented in column (4) of Table 3. We find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.024, t = −2.71), consistent with our earlier findings, and thus our results remain unchanged. We also rerun our main regression model using data on chairmen’s birthplaces from the CSMAR database. Using the definition of Individualism provided in Section 3.2, we find that β is significantly negative (β = −0.023, t = −2.30), as shown in column (5) of Table 3. Taken together, these results suggest that our H1 is robust to a battery of alternative checks. Note that 1988 is the earliest year for which agriculture statistics are available from the National Bureau of Statistics of China. The sample size decreases to 12,494 observations after we delete 17 firm-year observations for chairmen whose birthplaces are in Tibet, Inner Mongolia or Xinjiang. 514 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 3. Regression results for H1. South-North region-fixed effect chairman’s (0–1) wheat/rice wheat/crops model birthplace logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Constant −0.444*** −0.455*** −0.451*** −0.095** −0.442*** (−3.70) (−3.78) (−3.75) (−2.12) (−3.68) logsales 1.575*** 1.584*** 1.589*** 1.474*** 1.575*** -10.54 -10.59 -10.63 -10.97 -10.53 Logsales*Individualism −0.023** −0.050*** −0.072*** −0.024*** −0.023** (−2.34) (−2.79) (−3.87) (−2.71) (−2.30) logsales*Ownership 0.011 0.01 0.011 0.005 0.011 -1.11 -0.99 -1.08 -0.53 -1.12 logsales*GDPG 0.129 0.129 0.135 0.166 0.125 -0.56 -0.55 -0.58 -0.79 -0.54 logsales*AI −0.006*** −0.006*** −0.006*** −0.004** −0.006*** (−2.92) (−3.01) (−3.07) (−2.04) (−2.92) logsales*EI −1.350*** −1.325*** −1.327*** −1.229*** −1.353*** (−4.24) (−4.16) (−4.17) (−4.27) (−4.24) logsales*Uncertainty 0.007 0.007 0.005 −0.007 0.007 -0.66 -0.65 -0.48 (−0.73) -0.65 logsales*Size −0.001 −0.001 −0.001 0 −0.001 (−0.33) (−0.22) (−0.14) -0.1 (−0.33) logsales*Leverage 0.111*** 0.109*** 0.107*** 0.084*** 0.111*** -4.75 -4.66 -4.6 -4.04 -4.75 logsales*Age −0.171*** −0.171*** −0.171*** −0.151*** −0.171*** (−5.15) (−5.14) (−5.14) (−5.04) (−5.14) logsales*Tenure 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.013*** 0.011*** 0.013*** -3.07 -3.04 -3.09 -2.92 -3.04 logsales*Gender 0.047** 0.047** 0.048** 0.044** 0.047** -2.52 -2.52 -2.53 -2.45 -2.52 logsales*Independent 0.02 0.023 0.021 0.059 0.02 -0.3 -0.34 -0.31 -0.97 -0.3 logsales*Duality 0.013 0.011 0.011 0.01 0.013 -0.96 -0.82 -0.83 -0.81 -0.95 Individualism 0.002 0.02 0.021 0.005 0.003 -0.31 -1.34 -1.34 -1.48 -0.31 Ownership 0 −0.000 −0.000 −0.001 0 -0.01 (−0.00) (−0.00) (−0.39) -0.01 GDPG 1.245*** 1.247*** 1.246*** - 1.242*** -4.01 -4.03 -4.03 - -4 AI −0.001 −0.001 −0.001 0 −0.001 (−0.50) (−0.50) (−0.48) -0.59 (−0.50) EI 0.349** 0.346** 0.347** 0.353*** 0.347** -2.54 -2.51 -2.52 -4.54 -2.52 Uncertainty −0.006 −0.006 −0.006 −0.003 −0.006 (−1.05) (−1.03) (−0.94) (−0.66) (−1.05) Size 0.016*** 0.016*** 0.016*** 0.002* 0.016*** -5.06 -5.02 -4.98 -1.9 -5.04 Leverage 0.013 0.014 0.014 −0.006 0.012 -0.99 -1.07 -1.12 (−0.83) -0.99 Age 0.001 0.002 0.001 0.011 0.001 -0.05 -0.09 -0.06 -1.11 -0.04 Tenure 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 -0.66 -0.66 -0.68 -0.42 -0.68 Gender −0.014 −0.013 −0.014 −0.003 −0.014 (−0.97) (−0.91) (−0.96) (−0.53) (−0.97) Independent −0.030 −0.031 −0.032 0.007 −0.031 (−0.89) (−0.91) (−0.93) -0.29 (−0.90) Duality −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 0.001 −0.004 (−0.79) (−0.73) (−0.73) -0.4 (−0.78) Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Region FE Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N 12,511 12,511 12,511 12,511 12,494 Adj. R 0.854 0.854 0.854 0.879 0.854 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 515 4.2.2. Robustness check Next, we conduct a change analysis. Specifically, we first choose a sample of firms whose chairmen were replaced and construct the variable ΔIndividualism, which equals 1 if a collectivistic chairman is replaced by an individualistic chairman, −1 if the reverse change occurs or 0 if replacement of the chairman does not lead to a change between individualism and collectivism. Second, following Irvine et al. (2016), we measure firm-specific cost elasticity (CE) by logðCOGS =COGS Þ= logðSales =Sales Þ and test whether a change in cost elas- i;t i;t 1 i;t i;t 1 ticity is associated with a change in chairman individualism. Third, we expect that the incoming chairman will take some time to adjust the firm’s cost structure; therefore, we regress the change in cost elasticity (∆CE ) on the lagged change in chairman t+1 individualism (∆Individualism ). The results are presented in Table 4. We find that the coefficient on the lagged change in chairman individualism is significantly negative, suggesting that an increase in individualism due to chairman change leads to a decrease in a firm’s cost elasticity. We re-examine our H1 using a sample of Chinese listed companies in the manufactur- ing industry, which account for over 60% of our full sample, as strategic cost management is especially important for manufacturing firms (Chang et al., 2017). The results are presented in Table 5, which demonstrates that our H1 holds for all of the analyses except that shown in column (5). The literature shows that chairmen play an important leadership role in board meetings, where they have the ultimate power to set the tone of meetings and thus directly affect firms’ strategic and major business decisions (Jiang & Kim, 2015; Zhu et al., 2016). Undeniably, CEOs also strongly influence firms’ strategic and major business decisions. Therefore, we use a CEO’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for individualism (collectivism) and examine the effect of CEO individualism on firms’ cost elasticity. Furthermore, we perform the same alter- native checks for CEO individualism as described for chairman individualism in Section 4.2.1. The results are shown in Table 6. We find that although β2 is still negative, the effect of CEO individualism on cost elasticity is less significantly negative than that of chairman individualism. The results suggest that individualistic CEOs have a smaller impact on firms’ cost structure decisions than individualistic chairmen do. 4.2.3. Tests of H2–H4 H2 predicts that the negative association between chairman individualism and flex - ibility of cost structure will be less pronounced in SOEs than in non-SOEs. Table 7 presents the regression results for H2. In the subsample analysis, columns (1) and (2) respectively show that β is significantly negative (β = −0.032, t = −1.87) for non- Our sample period includes 4,157 firm-year observations involving changes in chairmen but only 578 observations that disclose complete information about the chairmen’s native places of origin before and after the changes in chairmen. Finally, our sample size for the change model decreases to 499 observations after deleting firm-year observations with missing values for control variables. In the regression model, we also control for CEO age (Age), tenure (Tenure) and gender (Gender). 516 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 4. Change analysis. Variables ΔCE Constant −1.044 (−0.25) ΔIndividualism −1.480** (−2.15) ΔOwnership −2.496 (−1.46) ΔGDPG 3.73 -0.34 ΔAI −0.285 (−1.00) ΔEI −18.539 (−0.51) ΔUncertainty −1.602 (−0.99) ΔSize 0.259 -0.28 ΔLeverage −0.912 (−0.28) ΔAge −2.307 (−1.18) ΔTenure 0.085 -0.27 ΔGender −0.156 (−0.11) ΔIndependent −16.195** (−2.48) ΔDuality 0.72 -0.85 Firm FE Yes Year FE Yes N 499 Adj. R 0.115 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. SOEs but nonsignificant (β = 0.001, t = 0.10) for SOEs, which is consistent with H2. We further divide SOEs into those administrated by the central government and by local governments and find that β remains nonsignificant (β = 0.015, t = 0.85 and β = 0.000, t = 0.03, respectively), as shown in columns (3) and (4). The results suggest in SOEs, the collectivistic culture and political promotion pressure mitigate the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions. Therefore, individualistic chairmen of SOEs are likely to choose a more flexible cost structure, whereas individualistic chairmen of non-SOEs are likely to choose a less flexible cost structure because their firms are less influenced by collectivism. H3 predicts that the negative association between chairman individualism and flex - ibility of cost structure will be less pronounced in firms whose boards of directors are The results of a test of differences in coefficients between subsamples show that β is significantly different between SOEs and non-SOEs. In the following subsample difference tests for H3 and H4, which test the moderating effects of board independence and financial leverage, respectively, we obtain similar results, which are not described below. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 517 Table 5. Regression results for H1-Manufacturing industry sample. South-North region-fixed (0–1) wheat/rice wheat/crops effect model chairman’s birthplace logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Constant −0.680*** −0.705*** −0.704*** −0.092** −0.679*** (−5.38) (−5.56) (−5.57) (−1.97) (−5.38) logsales 1.694*** 1.727*** 1.736*** 1.674*** 1.690*** -10.49 -10.69 -10.76 -11.42 -10.46 Logsales*Individualism −0.020* −0.081*** −0.107*** −0.026*** −0.017 (−1.83) (−4.07) (−5.27) (−2.64) (−1.56) logsales*Ownership 0.009 0.009 0.01 0.003 0.008 -0.8 -0.82 -0.9 -0.27 -0.76 logsales*GDPG 0.088 0.062 0.078 −0.040 0.093 -0.33 -0.24 -0.29 (−0.16) -0.35 logsales*AI −0.018*** −0.018*** −0.018*** −0.013*** −0.018*** (−6.13) (−6.13) (−6.21) (−5.06) (−6.13) logsales*EI 0.629* 0.694* 0.675* 0.197 0.620* -1.68 -1.86 -1.81 -0.58 -1.66 logsales*Uncertainty 0.045*** 0.042*** 0.038*** 0.022* 0.045*** -3.35 -3.13 -2.9 -1.83 -3.38 logsales*Size −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 −0.004 (−0.90) (−0.80) (−0.82) (−0.96) (−0.92) logsales*Leverage 0.047* 0.047* 0.043* 0.051** 0.047* -1.79 -1.78 -1.65 -2.13 -1.79 logsales*Age −0.189*** −0.189*** −0.187*** −0.171*** −0.187*** (−5.34) (−5.38) (−5.32) (−5.33) (−5.31) logsales*Tenure 0.020*** 0.020*** 0.021*** 0.015*** 0.020*** -3.93 -4.03 -4.12 -3.39 -3.92 logsales*Gender −0.010 −0.013 −0.014 −0.018 −0.010 (−0.35) (−0.48) (−0.50) (−0.68) (−0.36) logsales*Independent 0.126* 0.127* 0.120* 0.133* 0.125* -1.72 -1.73 -1.65 -1.93 -1.72 logsales*Duality 0.012 0.007 0.008 0.003 0.012 -0.83 -0.52 -0.56 -0.21 -0.84 Individualism 0.006 0.043** 0.050*** 0.007** 0.007 -0.72 -2.41 -2.84 -1.96 -0.83 Ownership 0.001 0 0 −0.002 0.001 -0.15 -0.02 -0.04 (−0.73) -0.14 GDPG 1.812*** 1.845*** 1.838*** - 1.811*** -5.59 -5.71 -5.7 - -5.59 AI 0.003* 0.003* 0.003* 0.001 0.003* -1.88 -1.92 -1.95 -0.84 -1.88 EI 0.327** 0.326** 0.337** 0.146 0.327** -2.05 -2.05 -2.12 -1.59 -2.05 Uncertainty −0.005 −0.004 −0.003 −0.013** −0.005 (−0.65) (−0.52) (−0.38) (−2.11) (−0.66) Size 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.021*** 0.004*** 0.021*** -6.15 -6.12 -6.13 -2.72 -6.15 Leverage 0.02 0.022* 0.023* 0.004 0.02 -1.56 -1.69 -1.76 -0.5 -1.56 Age 0.017 0.019 0.018 0.004 0.017 -0.8 -0.87 -0.81 -0.36 -0.78 Tenure 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.002 0.001 -0.48 -0.54 -0.6 -1.22 -0.48 Gender −0.021 −0.021 −0.022 0.006 −0.020 (−1.23) (−1.27) (−1.33) -0.82 (−1.22) Independent −0.040 −0.042 −0.042 0.002 −0.039 (−1.12) (−1.19) (−1.21) -0.08 (−1.11) Duality −0.001 −0.000 −0.000 0.001 −0.001 (−0.19) (−0.03) (−0.03) -0.14 (−0.21) Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Region FE Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N 7,545 7,545 7,545 7,545 7,539 Adj. R 0.882 0.882 0.882 0.901 0.882 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. 518 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN more (vs. less) independent. We divide the full sample into High_Indepen and Low_Indepen subsamples according to the yearly median value of Independent and examine the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost elasticity. Table 8 presents the regression results for H3. The results of the subsample analysis are presented in columns (1) and (2), which respectively show that β is nonsignificant (β = −0.012, t = −0.74) for the High_Indepen subsample but significantly negative (β = −0.047, t = −3.62) for the Low_Indepen subsample, which is consistent with H3. The results imply in firms with more independent directors, individualistic chairmen’s risk-taking behaviours attract attention from the independent directors, who can impose restrictions on firms’ cost structure decisions. H4 predicts that the negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure will be less pronounced when firms’ financial leverage is higher (vs. lower). We divide the full sample into High_Lev and Low_Lev subsamples according to the yearly median value of Leverage and examine the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost elasticity. Table 9 presents the regression results for H4. Columns (1) and (2) show that β is nonsignificant (β = −0.006, t = −0.51) for the High_Lev subsample but significantly negative (β = −0.032, t = −1.85) for the Low_Lev sample, which is consistent with H4. The results suggest in a firm with higher financial leverage, an individualistic chairman is highly incentivised to control the firm’s overall risk by choosing a more flexible cost structure (i.e. lower operating leverage). 4.2.4. Additional tests We perform the following tests to further validate our results. First, we delete firm– year observations wherein chairmen also hold CEO positions. Second, we construct an alternative continuous variable of chairman individualism which is the percentage of cultivated land used for rice farming in the province that corresponds to a chairman’s native place of origin, and rerun our regressions. Third, we exclude firm- year observations wherein the chairmen’s native places of origin are in Sichuan, Chongqing, Anhui, Hubei, Jiangsu and Guizhou because these provinces lie along the boundary between Northern and Southern China. Fourth, we control for the chairman’s education level using the following scores: 1 = associate’s degree, 2 = bachelor’s degree, 3 = master’s degree and 4 = doctor’s degree. As the CSMAR database does not contain complete information on all chairmen’s education levels, we assume chairmen with lower levels of education are less willing to disclose this information; therefore, we set 0 = missing education level. Last, we control for a chairman’s compensation. As not all compensation is paid by the listed company, we control for both the payment of chairman’s compensation by the listed company and the amount of cash compensation. Our results remain robust after conducting these additional tests. The dual position of chairman and CEO may increase a chairman’s overconfidence and thus substitute for the effect of chairman individualism (collectivism). Nevertheless, we do not find a significantly negative association between chairman individualism and cost elasticity when a chairman holds a CEO position. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 519 Table 6. Regression results for H1-CEO Sample. South-North region-fixed (0–1) wheat/rice wheat/crops effect model chairman’s birthplace logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Constant −0.447** −0.462** −0.473** −0.156** −0.447** (−2.35) (−2.43) (−2.49) (−2.33) (−2.35) logsales 1.079*** 1.082*** 1.082*** 0.974*** 1.072*** -4.62 -4.63 -4.63 -4.8 -4.58 Logsales*Individualism −0.028* −0.025 −0.037 −0.026* −0.028* (−1.80) (−0.91) (−1.37) (−1.91) (−1.82) logsales*Ownership −0.024 −0.027* −0.026* −0.023* −0.024 (−1.58) (−1.75) (−1.71) (−1.72) (−1.59) logsales*GDPG 0.549 0.568* 0.567* 0.362 0.559* -1.62 -1.68 -1.67 -1.2 -1.65 logsales*AI −0.003 −0.003 −0.003 −0.002 −0.004 (−1.24) (−1.22) (−1.25) (−1.03) (−1.30) logsales*EI −2.201*** −2.226*** −2.216*** −1.845*** −2.188*** (−5.29) (−5.34) (−5.32) (−5.12) (−5.24) logsales*Uncertainty −0.012 −0.010 −0.011 −0.002 −0.012 (−0.71) (−0.58) (−0.65) (−0.13) (−0.72) logsales*Size −0.014** −0.014** −0.014** −0.008* −0.014** (−2.56) (−2.51) (−2.47) (−1.68) (−2.53) logsales*Leverage 0.146*** 0.144*** 0.143*** 0.114*** 0.147*** -4.24 -4.19 -4.15 -3.84 -4.26 logsales*Age 0.003 0.001 0.002 0.012 0.004 -0.06 -0.03 -0.05 -0.27 -0.07 logsales*Tenure 0.004 0.005 0.004 0.007 0.005 -0.7 -0.73 -0.69 -1.3 -0.8 logsales*Gender 0.046* 0.048* 0.048* 0.026 0.045* -1.77 -1.87 -1.86 -1.15 -1.75 logsales*Independent 0.355*** 0.352*** 0.352*** 0.266*** 0.356*** -3.36 -3.33 -3.33 -2.87 -3.37 logsales*Duality 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 0.006 -0.38 -0.34 -0.34 -0.44 -0.36 Individualism 0.032*** 0.061*** 0.069*** 0.003 0.033*** -2.64 -2.78 -2.98 -0.6 -2.7 Ownership −0.022 −0.021 −0.021 −0.003 −0.023 (−1.52) (−1.42) (−1.44) (−0.63) (−1.53) GDPG 0.798 0.785 0.8 - 0.849* -1.64 -1.61 -1.64 - -1.74 AI 0.003* 0.003* 0.002* 0.001 0.003** -1.88 -1.75 -1.7 -1.17 -2.03 EI 0.545*** 0.560*** 0.563*** 0.505*** 0.526*** -2.74 -2.82 -2.83 -4.9 -2.64 Uncertainty 0.005 0.005 0.005 −0.015** 0.006 -0.52 -0.52 -0.52 (−2.00) -0.61 Size 0.015*** 0.014*** 0.015*** 0.005*** 0.015*** -2.94 -2.79 -2.86 -2.63 -2.91 Leverage −0.019 −0.018 −0.016 −0.017 −0.019 (−0.94) (−0.87) (−0.78) (−1.63) (−0.94) Age 0.002 0.005 0.004 0.011 0.001 -0.05 -0.15 -0.12 -0.72 -0.04 Tenure 0.001 0.001 0.001 0 0.001 -0.31 -0.31 -0.35 -0.12 -0.27 Gender 0.035* 0.035* 0.035 0.008 0.035* -1.66 -1.69 -1.64 -0.94 -1.66 Independent −0.030 −0.034 −0.033 0.01 −0.029 (−0.57) (−0.64) (−0.61) -0.29 (−0.54) Duality 0.002 0.002 0.002 0.001 0.002 -0.24 -0.26 -0.27 -0.29 -0.26 Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Region FE Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes N 6,800 6,800 6,800 6,800 6,785 Adj. R 0.826 0.826 0.826 0.864 0.826 Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. 520 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 7. Regression results for H2. Non-SOEs SOEs Central SOEs Local SOEs logCOGS (1) (2) (3) (4) Constant −0.193 −0.339** −0.494** −0.230 (−0.91) (−2.53) (−2.28) (−1.36) logsales 1.049*** 1.591*** 1.872*** 1.523*** (4.32) (8.87) (6.64) (6.69) Logsales*Individualism −0.032* 0.001 0.015 0.000 (−1.87) (0.10) (0.85) (0.03) logsales*GDPG 0.471 −0.040 0.239 −0.176 (1.21) (−0.16) (0.59) (−0.56) logsales*AI −0.015*** 0.010*** −0.011** 0.012*** (−4.60) (4.32) (−2.20) (4.44) logsales*EI −0.608 −1.795*** 0.592 −2.104*** (−1.15) (−4.96) (0.84) (−4.82) logsales*Uncertainty 0.008 0.027** 0.014 0.021 (0.48) (2.02) (0.58) (1.34) logsales*Size 0.019*** −0.022*** −0.016** −0.020*** (2.70) (−5.12) (−2.39) (−3.58) Logsales*Leverage 0.141*** 0.079*** 0.084* 0.064* (3.85) (2.83) (1.68) (1.86) logsales*Age −0.178*** −0.031 −0.137* −0.016 (−3.62) (−0.70) (−1.93) (−0.30) logsales*Tenure 0.019** 0.001 −0.012 0.004 (2.44) (0.30) (−1.43) (0.67) logsales*Gender 0.055** 0.024 0.097 0.014 (2.19) (0.75) (1.48) (0.37) logsales*Independent 0.157 −0.111 −0.321** −0.089 (1.42) (−1.52) (−2.40) (−1.02) logsales*Duality 0.047** −0.034* 0.044 −0.048** (2.48) (−1.74) (1.25) (−2.03) Individualism 0.000 −0.000 0.004 −0.008 (0.02) (−0.05) (0.46) (−0.69) GDPG 1.813*** 0.542* 0.437 0.422 (2.86) (1.70) (0.81) (1.07) AI −0.001 0.001 0.004 0.002 (−0.45) (0.93) (1.31) (1.13) EI 0.094 0.358** −0.296 0.454** (0.41) (2.15) (−0.92) (2.29) Uncertainty −0.008 −0.001 0.010 0.001 (−0.79) (−0.16) (0.80) (0.16) Size 0.012** 0.011*** 0.016*** 0.006 (2.14) (2.86) (2.81) (1.19) Leverage 0.015 0.004 −0.049** 0.016 (0.72) (0.28) (−2.05) (0.90) Age −0.024 0.004 0.012 0.006 (−0.66) (0.18) (0.33) (0.18) Tenure 0.002 0.002 −0.000 0.004 (0.50) (1.29) (−0.01) (1.59) Gender −0.052* −0.001 0.031 −0.011 (−1.75) (−0.09) (1.01) (−0.67) Independent −0.176*** 0.074** 0.059 0.090** (−2.80) (2.13) (0.98) (2.12) Duality −0.004 −0.007 −0.025** −0.003 (−0.53) (−1.10) (−2.12) (−0.37) Firm FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes N 6,162 6,349 1,694 4,655 Adj. R 0.823 0.901 0.924 0.894 p-value for diff . of β 0.086* - - Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 521 Table 8. Regression results for H3. High_Indepen Low_Indepen logCOGS (1) (2) Constant −0.204 −0.715*** (−0.93) (−4.47) logsales 1.412*** 1.601*** (5.59) (8.47) Logsales*Individualism −0.012 −0.047*** (−0.74) (−3.62) logsales*Ownership −0.014 0.038*** (−0.81) (2.96) logsales*GDPG −0.274 0.434 (−0.68) (1.50) logsales*AI −0.011*** −0.003 (−3.32) (−1.07) logsales*EI −2.060*** −1.367*** (−3.57) (−3.42) logsales*Uncertainty 0.018 0.013 (0.97) (0.89) logsales*Size −0.015** −0.002 (−2.19) (−0.41) logsales*Leverage 0.218*** 0.093*** (5.55) (3.10) logsales*Age −0.063 −0.177*** (−1.14) (−4.09) logsales*Tenure 0.018** 0.005 (2.53) (0.87) logsales*Gender 0.082** 0.064*** (2.30) (2.87) logsales*Duality 0.076*** −0.009 (3.44) (−0.48) Individualism 0.002 0.006 (0.16) (0.50) Ownership 0.005 −0.005 (0.25) (−0.41) GDPG 1.955*** 1.418*** (3.23) (3.59) AI −0.001 −0.003** (−0.30) (−2.11) EI 0.995*** 0.277 (3.62) (1.59) Uncertainty −0.018* −0.008 (−1.69) (−0.95) Size 0.007 0.022*** (1.25) (5.21) Leverage 0.038* 0.014 (1.68) (0.87) Age −0.039 0.036 (−1.05) (1.21) Tenure 0.006* −0.000 (1.67) (−0.04) Gender −0.002 −0.019 (−0.07) (−1.04) Duality −0.012 0.005 (−1.28) (0.66) Firm FE Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes N 5,447 7,064 Adj. R 0.819 0.863 p-value for diff . of β 0.050** Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. 522 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Table 9. Regression results for H4. High_Lev Low_Lev logCOGS (1) (2) Constant −0.271* −0.452** (−1.75) (−2.02) logsales 1.478*** 1.676*** (8.23) (6.22) Logsales*Individualism −0.006 −0.032* (−0.51) (−1.85) logsales*Ownership 0.011 0.014 (0.94) (0.77) logsales*GDPG 0.345 0.128 (1.21) (0.32) logsales*AI 0.006** −0.022*** (2.56) (−6.13) logsales*EI −1.246*** −0.852 (−3.12) (−1.58) logsales*Uncertainty 0.006 0.006 (0.49) (0.29) logsales*Size 0.000 −0.006 (0.03) (−0.84) logsales*Age −0.128*** −0.172*** (−3.10) (−3.01) logsales*Tenure 0.007 0.005 (1.40) (0.57) logsales*Gender −0.012 0.133*** (−0.51) (4.21) logsales*Independent −0.004 0.117 (−0.06) (0.90) logsales*Duality −0.018 0.070*** (−1.03) (3.16) Individualism 0.010 −0.013 (1.05) (−0.77) Ownership 0.020* 0.017 (1.84) (1.02) GDPG 0.820** 0.755 (2.04) (1.39) AI 0.001 −0.003 (0.88) (−1.29) EI 0.200 0.676*** (1.12) (2.72) Uncertainty −0.002 −0.015 (−0.22) (−1.31) Size 0.006 0.019*** (1.63) (3.04) Age 0.002 0.006 (0.06) (0.17) Tenure 0.000 0.006 (0.16) (1.54) Gender 0.007 −0.030 (0.44) (−0.97) Independent 0.052 −0.086 (1.20) (−1.49) Duality 0.001 −0.018** (0.15) (−2.08) Firm FE Yes Yes Year FE Yes Yes N 6,253 6,258 Adj. R 0.897 0.772 p-value for diff . of β 0.091* Note: ***, ** and * denote significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. t-statistics are reported in parentheses. CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 523 5. Conclusion The increasing complexity of supply chain management may expose firms to substantial risk. Accordingly, a growing body of literature in the field of management accounting investigates firms’ cost structure decisions in response to risk. However, the literature primarily focuses on demand-side risk such as demand uncertainty and customer concentration. Few studies pay attention to risk related to managers’ personal traits and firms’ incentive systems (Aboody et al., 2018). Investigation of firms’ cost structure decisions from the perspective of manager-side risk has important theoretical and practical implications. Accordingly, we examine the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions in a sample of Chinese listed companies, using a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for indivi- dualism (collectivism). Our results show that individualistic chairmen tend to choose a less flexible cost structure. Furthermore, the negative association between chairman individualism and flexibility of cost structure is less pronounced for SOEs (vs. non-SOEs), firms with more (vs. less) independent boards of directors and firms with higher (vs. lower) financial leverage. Our study presents both theoretical contributions and practical implications. It contri- butes to the growing literature on firms’ cost structure decisions in response to risk and extends the literature on the effects of individual-level individualism (collectivism) on corporate finance and financial accounting decisions to the study of management account- ing decisions, especially strategic cost management. Our study also provides insights into firms’ strategic cost management practices. It changes the paradigm wherein most knowl- edge on structural cost management comes from fields outside accounting, and it provides practical guidance for firms’ managers, accountants and the government. In particular, our findings may assist the Ministry of Finance in improving and implementing the ‘Fundamental Guidelines for Management Accounting’. Overall, our study provides empiri- cal evidence on the importance of managers’ leadership on Chinese firms’ strategic cost management, which can help firms to achieve transformation and sustainable development. Our study has two main limitations. First, regarding the challenge of measuring culture (i.e. individualism vs. collectivism) at the firm or individual level, although this paper tries to use a chairman’s native place of origin in Northern (Southern) China as a proxy for chair- man individualism (collectivism), we still cannot fully rule out the confounding effects of the discrepancy between Northern and Southern China. Future studies can explore more direct and accurate measures. Second, our paper only examines the effect of chairman individualism on firms’ cost structure decisions from the perspective of structural cost management, future research could also investigate how chairman individualism affects firms’ executional cost management, such as corporate strategy implementation and performance. Disclosure statement No potential conflict of interest was reported by the author(s). 524 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN References Aberdeen Group. (2005). Center-Led procurement-organizing resources and technology for sustained supply value. Boston. Abernethy, M.A., & Wallis, M. (2019). Critique on the “manager effects” research and implications for management accounting research. Journal of Management Accounting Research, 31(1), 3–40. https://doi.org/10.2308/jmar-52030 Aboody, D., Levi, S., & Weiss, D. (2018). Managerial incentives, options, and cost-structure choices. Review of Accounting Studies, 23(2), 422–451. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-017-9432-0 Adams, R.B., & Ferreira, D. (2009). Women in the boardroom and their impact on governance and performance. Journal of Financial Economics, 94(2), 291–309. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco. 2008.10.007 Alesina, A., & Giuliano, P. (2015). Culture and institutions. Journal of Economic Literature, 53(4), 898–944. https://doi.org/10.1257/jel.53.4.898 Anderson, M.C., Banker, R.D., & Janakiraman, S.N. (2003). Are selling, general, and administrative costs “sticky”? Journal of Accounting Research, 41(1), 47–63. https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-679X. Anderson, S.W., & Dekker, H.C. (2009a). Strategic cost management in supply chains, part 1: Structural cost management. Accounting Horizons, 23(2), 201–220. https://doi.org/10.2308/acch. 2009.23.2.201 Anderson, S.W., & Dekker, H.C. (2009b). Strategic cost management in supply chains, part 2: Executional cost management. Accounting Horizons, 23(3), 289–305. https://doi.org/10.2308/ acch.2009.23.3.289 Banker, R.D., Byzalov, D., & Plehn-Dujowich, J.M. (2014). Demand uncertainty and cost behavior. The Accounting Review, 89(3), 839–865. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50661 Becker, G. (1996). Preferences and values. Harvard University Press. Bennedsen, M., Nielsen, K.M., Pérez-González, F., & Wolfenzon, D. (2007). Inside the family firm: The role of families in succession decisions and performance. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (2), 647–691. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.122.2.647 Bertrand, M., & Schoar, A. (2003). Managing with style: The effect of managers on firm policies. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(4), 1169–1208. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355303322552775 Brochet, F., Miller, G.S., Naranjo, P., & Yu, G. (2019). Managers’ cultural background and disclosure attributes. The Accounting Review, 94(3), 57–86. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-52290 Cao, X., Lemmon, M., Pan, X., Qian, M., & Tian, G. (2019). Political promotion, CEO incentives, and the relationship between pay and performance. Management Science, 65(7), 2947–2965. https://doi. org/10.1287/mnsc.2017.2966 Carpenter, S. (2000). Effects of cultural tightness and collectivism on self-concept and causal attributions. Cross-Cultural Research, 34(1), 38–56. https://doi.org/10.1177/106939710003400103 Chang, H., Hall, C.M., & Paz, M. (2017). Customer concentration and cost structure. Working paper, https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?Abstract_id=2482777 . Chen, J., Ezzamel, M., & Cai, Z. (2011). Managerial power theory, tournament theory, and executive pay in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(4), 1176–1199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin. 2011.04.008 Chen, D., & Xiang, J. (2017). Is it reasonable for independent directors to be re-elected for only six years? Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Management World, (5), 144–157. (In Chinese). https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2017.05.013 Chui, A.C., Titman, S., & Wei, K.J. (2010). Individualism and momentum around the world. The Journal of Finance, 65(1), 361–392. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2009.01532.x Cronqvist, H., Makhija, A.K., & Yonker, S.E. (2012). Behavioral consistency in corporate finance: CEO personal and corporate leverage. Journal of Financial Economics, 103(1), 20–40. https://doi.org/10. 1016/j.jfineco.2011.08.005 Eun, C.S., Wang, L., & Xiao, S.C. (2015). Culture and R2. Journal of Financial Economics, 115(2), 283–303. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2014.09.003 CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 525 Fan, J.P., Gu, Q.K., & Yu, X. (2022). Collectivist cultures and the emergence of family firms, The Journal of Law and Economics, 65(S1), S293–S325. forthcoming. https://ssrn.com/abstract=3839978 . Fan, J.P., Wong, T.J., & Zhang, T. (2007). Politically connected CEOs, corporate governance, and Post- IPO performance of China’s newly partially privatized firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 84(2), 330–357. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2006.03.008 Fei, X. (1985). From the Soil - The Foundations of Chinese Society. SDX Joint Publishing Company. Firth, M., Leung, T.Y., Rui, O.M., & Na, C. (2015). Relative pay and its effects on firm efficiency in a transitional economy. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 110, 59–77. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.jebo.2014.12.001 Fiske, A.P., Kitayama, S., Markus, H.R., & Nisbett, R.E. (1998). The cultural matrix of social psychology. McGraw-Hill. Galasso, A., & Simcoe, T.S. (2011). CEO overconfidence and innovation. Management Science, 57(8), 1469–1484. https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1110.1374 Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., & Zingales, L. (2006). Does culture affect economic outcomes? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 23–48. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.20.2.23 Han, S., Kang, T., Salter, S., & Yoo, Y.K. (2010). A cross-country study on the effects of national culture on earnings management. Journal of International Business Studies, 41(1), 123–141. https://doi. org/10.1057/jibs.2008.78 Hayward, M.L., & Hambrick, D.C. (1997). Explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions: Evidence of CEO hubris. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42(1), 103–127. https://doi.org/10. 2307/2393810 Heine, S.J. (2008). Cultural psychology. W.W. Norton & Company. Hofstede, G. (1980). Culture’s consequences. Sage Publications. Hofstede, G. (2001). Culture’s consequences: Comparing values, behaviors, institutions and organiza- tions across nations. Sage Publications. Holzhacker, M., Krishnan, R., & Mahlendorf, M.D. (2015a). The impact of changes in regulation on cost behavior. Contemporary Accounting Research, 32(2), 534–566. https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846. Holzhacker, M., Krishnan, R., & Mahlendorf, M.D. (2015b). Unraveling the black box of cost behavior: An empirical investigation of risk drivers, managerial resource procurement, and cost elasticity. The Accounting Review, 90(6), 2305–2335. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-51092 Irvine, P.J., Park, S.S., & Yıldızhan, Ç. (2016). Customer-Base Concentration, Profitability, and the Relationship Life Cycle. The Accounting Review, 91(3), 883–906. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr- Jiang, W., Di, L., & Yao, W. (2017). Customer concentration and firm cost stickiness: Evidence from Chinese listed companies in manufacturing industry. Journal of Financial Research, (9), 192–206. https://kns.cnki.net Jiang, W., Hu, Y., & Zeng, Y. (2015). Financial constraints and cost stickiness: Evidence from Chinese industrial firms. Journal of Financial Research, (10), 133–147. https://kns.cnki.net Jiang, F., & Kim, K.A. (2015). Corporate governance in China: A modern perspective. Journal of Corporate Finance, 32, 190–216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.10.010 Jiang, W., Lin, B., Liu, Y., & Xu, Y. (2019). Chairperson collectivism and the compensation gap between managers and employees: Evidence from China. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 27(4), 261–282. https://doi.org/10.1111/corg.12278 Jiang, W., Sun, Y., & Hu, Y. (2018). Customer concentration and cost structure decisions: Empirical evidence from Chinese Relation-oriented business environment. Accounting Research, (11), 70–76. https://kns.cnki.net Jiang, W., Wan, H., & Zhao, S. (2016). Reputation concerns of independent directors: Evidence from individual director voting. The Review of Financial Studies, 29(3), 655–696. https://doi.org/10.1093/ rfs/hhv125 Jiang, W., Yao, W., & Hu, Y. (2016). The enforcement of the Minimum Wage Policy in China and firm cost stickiness. China Journal of Accounting Studies, 4(3), 339–355. https://doi.org/10.1080/ 21697213.2016.1218631 526 W. JIANG AND Y. SUN Kallapur, S., & Eldenburg, L. (2005). Uncertainty, real options, and cost behavior: Evidence from Washington state hospitals. Journal of Accounting Research, 43(5), 735–752. https://doi.org/10. 1111/j.1475-679X.2005.00188.x Kanagaretnam, K., Lim, C.Y., & Lobo, G.J. (2011). Effects of national culture on earnings quality of banks. Journal of International Business Studies, 42(6), 853–874. https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2011. Kanagaretnam, K., Lim, C.Y., & Lobo, G.J. (2014). Influence of national culture on accounting conservatism and risk-taking in the banking industry. The Accounting Review, 89(3), 1115–1149. https://doi.org/10.2308/accr-50682 Ke, B., Rui, O., & Yu, W. (2012). Hong Kong stock listing and the sensitivity of managerial compensa- tion to firm performance in state-controlled Chinese firms. Review of Accounting Studies, 17(1), 166–188. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11142-011-9169-0 Kim, J.B., Wang, Z., & Zhang, L. (2016). CEO overconfidence and stock price crash risk. Contemporary Accounting Research, 33(4), 1720–1749. https://doi.org/10.1111/1911-3846.12217 Krause, R., Semadeni, M., & Withers, M.C. (2016). That special someone: When the board views its chair as a resource. Strategic Management Journal, 37(9), 1990–2002. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj. Kulkarni, S.P., Hudson, T., Ramamoorthy, N., Marchev, A., Georgieva-Kondakova, P., & Gorskov, V. (2010). Dimensions of individualism-collectivism: A comparative study of five cultures. Current Issues of Business & Law, 5(1), 93–109. https://doi.org/10.5200/1822-9530.2010.03 Liang, S., Chen, D., & Hu, X. (2015). External auditor types and the cost stickiness of listed companies. Accounting Research, (2), 79–86. https://kns.cnki.net Li, K., Griffin, D., Yue, H., & Zhao, L. (2013). How does culture influence corporate risk-taking? Journal of Corporate Finance, 23, 1–22. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2013.07.008 Liu, C., Li, S., & Sun, L. (2015). Do independent directors have the consulting function? An empirical study on the function of independent directors in strange land. Management World, (3), 124–136. (In Chinese). https://doi.org/10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2015.03.012 Liu, S.S., Morris, M.W., Talhelm, T., & Yang, Q. (2019). Ingroup vigilance in collectivistic cultures. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 116(29), 14538–14546. https://doi.org/10.1073/ pnas.1817588116 Liu, H., Qi, Y., & Wang, H. (2017). On the cost stickiness difference between companies with different layers in pyramidal business group. Accounting Research, (7), 82–88. https://kns.cnki. net Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2005). CEO overconfidence and corporate investment. The Journal of Finance, 60(6), 2661–2700. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2011.01685.x Malmendier, U., & Tate, G. (2008). Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market’s reaction. Journal of Financial Economics, 89(1), 20–43. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2007.07. Malmendier, U., Tate, G., & Yan, J. (2011). Overconfidence and early-life experiences: The effect of managerial traits on corporate financial policies. The Journal of Finance, 66(5), 1687–1733. https:// doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2011.01685.x Mao, H., Li, Z., & Cheng, J. (2015). The effect of non-economic factors on asymmetric cost behavior: Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Naikai Management Review, (6), 136–145. https://kns. cnki.net Nguyen, D.D., Hagendorff, J., & Eshraghi, A. (2018). Does a CEO’s cultural heritage affect performance under competitive pressure? The Review of Financial Studies, 31(1), 97–141. https://doi.org/10. 1093/rfs/hhx046 Shweder, R.A. (1991). Thinking through cultures: Expeditions in cultural psychology. Harvard University Press. Singelis, T.M., Triandis, H.C., Bhawuk, D.P., & Gelfand, M.J. (1995). Horizontal and vertical dimensions of individualism and collectivism: A theoretical and measurement refinement. Cross-Cultural Research, 29(3), 240–275. https://doi.org/10.1177/106939719502900302 CHINA JOURNAL OF ACCOUNTING STUDIES 527 Talhelm, T., Zhang, X., Oishi, S., Shimin, C., Duan, D., Lan, X., & Kitayama, S. (2014). Large-scale psychological differences within China explained by rice versus wheat agriculture. Science, 344 (6184), 603–608. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1246850 Triandis, H.C. (2001). Individualism-collectivism and personality. Journal of Personality, 69(6), 907–924. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6494.696169 Wang, X., & Gao, K. (2017). Customer relationship and cost stickiness: Hold-up or cooperation. Naikai Management Review, (1), 132–142. https://kns.cnki.net Withers, M.C., & Fitza, M.A. (2017). Do board chairs matter? The influence of board chairs on firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, 38(6), 1343–1355. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2587 Ye, K., Zhu, J., Lu, Z., & Zhang, R. (2011). The Independence of independent directors: Evidence from board voting behavior. Economic Research Journal, (1), 126–139. https://kns.cnki.net Zhang, L., Li, J., Zhang, H., & Wang, H. (2019). Can managerial ability restrain company’s cost stickiness? Accounting Research, (3), 71–77. https://kns.cnki.net Zhou, L., Liu, H., & Zhang, H. (2019). How do former CEO directors affect corporate resource adjustment? Journal of Financial Research, (2), 169–187. https://kns.cnki.net Zhu, J., Ye, K., Tucker, J.W., & Chan, K.J.C. (2016). Board hierarchy, independent directors, and firm value: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 41, 262–279. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. jcorpfin.2016.09.009

Journal

China Journal of Accounting StudiesTaylor & Francis

Published: Oct 2, 2022

Keywords: Chairman individualism personal traits strategic cost management cost structure

References