Get 20M+ Full-Text Papers For Less Than $1.50/day. Start a 14-Day Trial for You or Your Team.

Learn More →

Discrete-Time Risk Models with Claim Correlated Premiums in a Markovian Environment

Discrete-Time Risk Models with Claim Correlated Premiums in a Markovian Environment risks Article Discrete-Time Risk Models with Claim Correlated Premiums in a Markovian Environment † ,† Dhiti Osatakul and Xueyuan Wu * Department of Economics, The University of Melbourne, Parkville, VIC 3010, Australia; dosatakul@student.unimelb.edu.au * Correspondence: xueyuanw@unimelb.edu.au; Tel.: +61-3-83447939 † These authors contributed equally to this work. Abstract: In this paper we consider a discrete-time risk model, which allows the premium to be adjusted according to claims experience. This model is inspired by the well-known bonus- malus system in the non-life insurance industry. Two strategies of adjusting periodic premiums are considered: aggregate claims or claim frequency. Recursive formulae are derived to compute the finite-time ruin probabilities, and Lundberg-type upper bounds are also derived to evaluate the ultimate-time ruin probabilities. In addition, we extend the risk model by considering an external Markovian environment in which the claims distributions are governed by an external Markov process so that the periodic premium adjustments vary when the external environment state changes. We then study the joint distribution of premium level and environment state at ruin given ruin occurs. Two numerical examples are provided at the end of this paper to illustrate the impact of the initial external environment state, the initial premium level and the initial surplus on the ruin probability. Keywords: discrete-time risk model; bonus-malus system; Markov modulated risk model; finite-time ruin; recursive computation; Lundberg inequality Citation: Osatakul, Dhiti, and Xueyuan Wu. 2021. Discrete-Time 1. Introduction Risk Models with Claim Correlated The commonly adopted bonus-malus system in the general insurance industry is Premiums in a Markovian based on a principal that insurance premiums can be adjusted based on the historical Environment. Risks 9: 26. claims record of individual policyholders. To be specific, the policyholders, who make no https://doi.org/10.3390/ claim or small claims in the latest policy year, will be offered a premium discount (also risks9010026 called ‘bonus’) on renewal. On the other hand, policyholders who make more claims than the given thresholds in the current policy year may need to pay higher premiums (also Received: 18 November 2020 called ‘malus’) if they decide to renew their policies. The bonus-malus system plays an Accepted: 10 January 2021 important role in the insurance industry, in particular in motor vehicle insurance sector, Published: 14 January 2021 because this system defines risk specific premium levels that help to sustain the total Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neu- premium pool in covering all motor insurance claims of the given insurance portfolio. The tral with regard to jurisdictional clai- discount in premium acts as an incentive to retain low-risk policyholders and to attract new ms in published maps and institutio- customers; on the other hand, the malus component prevents high-risk policyholders from nal affiliations. taking advantage of the low-risk policyholders by receiving disproportionate insurance benefits. The purpose of the bonus-malus system is to create heterogeneity by low-risk policyholders and high-risk policyholders. In other words, it acts as a posteriori classifier that differentiates the policyholders according to their driving behaviours besides the a Copyright: © 2021 by the authors. Li- priori variables. In addition, in terms of commercial purpose, the bonus-malus system censee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. is widely adopted in pricing by motor vehicle insurance companies to enhance their This article is an open access article competitiveness in the insurance market. distributed under the terms and con- The bonus-malus system related problems have remained a popular research field for ditions of the Creative Commons At- decades. De Pril (1979) proposed a continuous-time model for the bonus-malus system, tribution (CC BY) license (https:// which considers the phenomenon called ‘bonus-hunger ’. Lemaire and Zi (1994) conducted creativecommons.org/licenses/by/ a comparative analysis of 30 bonus-malus systems of 22 countries, and Lemaire (1995) 4.0/). Risks 2021, 9, 26. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks9010026 https://www.mdpi.com/journal/risks Risks 2021, 9, 26 2 of 23 provided insurance companies models to design their own bonus-malus systems that meet their objectives. Pinquet et al. (2001) considered the age of claims in their proposed model for the bonus-malus system. Baione et al. (2002) proposed the optimal bonus-malus system, which maximised the ‘transparency’ between policyholders and insurers and ‘financial balance conditions’. Pitrebois et al. (2006) designed a bonus-malus system with different types of claims. Dionne and Ghali (2005) conducted an empirical evaluation of the 1992 bonus-malus system in Tunisia. More recently, Denuit et al. (2019) consid- ered multivariate credibility modelling for usage-based motor insurance pricing with behavioural data, Vilar-Zanon et al. (2020) discussed an average model approach to experi- ence based premium rates discounts using the Spanish agricultural insurance data, and Ágoston and Gyetvai (2020) studied a joint optimisation problem of transition rules and the premium scale in a bonus-malus system. A lot more research work can be found in the references therein. The bonus-malus system has also been studied by many researchers in the context of risk models with claim-dependent premiums. As for the continuous-time setting, Afonso et al. (2009) studied the finite-time ruin probabilities in a continuous- time risk model that allows the premiums to be adjusted according to historical surplus levels. Li et al. (2015) studied the ruin probabilities under a continuous-time risk model with premium rate adjusted to the historical number of claims. Specifically, they applied the Bayesian credibility theory to find the posteriori expected number of claims and then adjusted the premium rate according to the posteriori estimator of claim numbers. They studied the impact of the two risks classified by ‘defectiveness’, i.e., the ‘historical’ stream and the ‘unforeseeable’ stream, on ruin probabilities. Constantinescu et al. (2016) studied the ruin probability in a regenerative risk process. They assume that the inter-arrival times of the process depend on the inter-arrival time between the current and previous claim. In other words, the distribution of the next claim waiting time depends on the waiting time between the current claim and the previous one. This assumption allows the premium rate to be adjusted according to the change of the inter-arrival time distribution. However, only two levels of premium rates are evaluated in their model: the bonus (discount) state and the base state. Moreover, Kucer ˇ ovský and Najafabadi (2017) studied the continuous-time risk model for a long term bonus-malus system in a steady state. They obtained the ruin probability in terms of closed-form solutions of an integral equation by the method of complex analysis. In addition, Afonso et al. (2017) analysed the impact of the different well-known bonus-malus scales and transition rules on the finite-time ruin probability in a continuous-time risk model. The posteriori premiums in their model are modified according to the historical claim record of each individual policyholder. In the most recent literature, Afonso et al. (2020) studied ruin probabilities and capital requirement for open automobile portfolios with a bonus-malus system based on claim counts. Under the discrete-time setting, Dufresne (1988) proposed the recursive algorithm to compute the ruin probabilities by using the stationary distributions of the bonus-malus system. Wagner (2002) considered a two-state Markov chain risk model and derived recur- sive formulae for ruin probabilities. Trufin and Loisel (2013) studied the ruin probabilities with premiums adjusted to the claims by Bühlmann credibility theory. They derived the asymptotic formulae for the ultimate ruin probabilities and the Lundberg coefficients for the light-tailed claims. In addition, they also derived the asymptotic formulae for the ulti- mate ruin probabilities for heavy-tailed claims. Further, Wu et al. (2015) derived recursive formulae and explicit formulae for the ultimate ruin probabilities in the case that premiums are correlated to claim amounts by using the two-state Markov Chain model. First of all, this paper is an extension of the models of Wu et al. (2015). As for the models of Wu et al. (2015), there are some strong assumptions regarding claim amounts and premiums. For example, the claims were assumed to take only three integer values and the differences between claims amount and premiums must be multiples of the lowest premium level. In addition, there are only three premium levels in their models. Taking into account these limitations, this paper aims to relax the strict assumptions such that Risks 2021, 9, 26 3 of 23 the individual claims can take any non-negative integer values and the premiums vary according to claims record in a broader bonus-malus context. Recursive equations are derived to calculate the finite-time ruin probabilities in the discrete-time setting. A similar approach was adopted in (Cai and Dickson (2004), sct. 2). In addition to considering premium adjustments according to aggregate claim amounts, this paper also considers the option of adjusting premiums based on recorded claim numbers, whereas Wu et al. (2015) only focused on the former case. Secondly, this paper combines inhomogeneity in claims experience with the bonus- malus system by introducing an external Markovian environment, which could see more applications in the real world. This is inspired by the fact that the external environment can affect the implementation of the bonus-malus system and should be taken into account by the insurers. As being said in Niemiec (2017), the external environment can affect the claim frequency and the bonus-malus system should be evaluated according to this factor. The term ‘external environment’ in this context means the factor that the insurers are not able to control but have an impact on the performance of the bonus-malus system. It can include economic conditions, weather conditions, regulations, competitiveness of competitors and so on. The topics about a bonus-malus system within an external environment have been studied by various researchers in the literature. For example, Viswanathan and Lemaire (2005) used a diffusion theory to study the evolution of market shares and claim frequencies of a two-company market when one insurance company applies the aggressive bonus-malus system. Park et al. (2010) used principal components analysis and regression models to evaluate the toughness of the bonus-malus system in Asia and its correlation with economic and cultural variables. Lee and Kim (2016) studied the impact of the change in a regulation of the bonus-malus system in Korea on moral hazard in motor vehicle insurance. Vilar-Zanon et al. (2020) introduced the new experience rating system, which is more suitable to the agricultural insurance in Spain and some other EU countries when high losses occur due to extreme weather. As for the studies of the risk of ruin within a Markovian environment, the most recent literature of Markov-modulated risk models includes Nie et al. (2020) and Li and Li (2020). In the former paper, the authors studied a discrete Markov-modulated risk model with delayed claims, random premium income, and a constant dividend barrier; whilst in the latter one, the authors studied some state-specific one-sided exit probabilities as well as the corresponding two-sided first exit probabilities in a Markov-modulated risk process. In this paper, we only focus on external environments that affect the implementation of the bonus-malus system in terms of varying the aggregate claims distribution such as economic environment and weather conditions. Regarding our proposed premium adjustment rules, we assume that the external environment is governed by an external Markov process. When the policies are renewed, the insurers will apply certain premium correction rules that correspond to the current external environment condition to determine the renewal premiums. As for a real-world application, it is not an issue in practice due to the short-term nature of most non-life insurance contracts. It means that the insurers are able to frequently modify the premium adjustment rules when the external environment changes. By applying this principle, it helps the insurers to better address the systematic risk when implementing the bonus-malus system in pricing. However, it can be tricky when insurers explain the environment-dependent premium changing rules to their policyholders since the rules are likely to change over time. The main goal of this paper is to numerically evaluate the impact of bonus-malus system on the ruin probabilities of the proposed risk models within an external Markovian environment. We aim to explore the following questions that may arise when imple- menting the bonus-malus system in practice through some numerical studies based on hypothetical assumptions: - What should the initial premium level be for new policyholders? - Which premium adjustment criterion is better in the proposed risk models: premiums adjusted by aggregate claims amount or premiums adjusted by claim frequency only? Risks 2021, 9, 26 4 of 23 - What is the likely impact of the initial external environment condition on the risk of ruin when the proposed premium adjustment rules are implemented? The main findings of our numerical studies are: - The choice of initial premium level for new policyholders is not an easy task. A low initial premium level tends to be very risky when the company’s initial capital amount is small. However, when the initial capital amount is sufficiently large, the insurer has more flexibility to lower the initial premium level that can attract more new policyholders and help with boosting the insurance business without significantly increasing the risk of insolvency. - The initial external environment condition does have a significant impact on the risk of ruin under the proposed premium adjustment rules, but the impact could be different from our first guess. - Adjusting premiums according to claim frequency can be riskier than the case of adjusting premiums by aggregate claims. This paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the models and assumptions of our study. Section 3 presents the finite-time ruin probabilities in a Markovian environment. Section 4 presents Lundberg inequalities for ruin probabilities. Section 5 presents the joint distribution of time of ruin, deficit, premium level and environment state at ruin. Section 6 provides some numerical studies with detailed comments. Concluding remarks and future research are given in Section 7. 2. Models and Assumptions + + Let c denote a premium level set where c = fc g , L = f1, 2, ..., lg, l 2 N , c 2 R . i i2L i Here c , i = 1, . . . , l, are premium levels per unit volume of risk. Let the external economic environmental status in time period [t 1, t), t 2 N be represented by a homogeneous and irreducible discrete-time Markov chainf J g with a finite state space R = f1, 2, ..., rg and t t2N a transition probability matrix P = [ p (g, h)] , where p (g, h) = P( J = hj J = g). J J g,h2R J t1 The stationary probability distribution of the Markov process is denoted by l = [l , ..., l ] 1 r where 0  l  1, i = 1, 2, . . . , r, and l = 1. Let fL g + be a stochastic process å t i i t2N i=1 monitoring the premium levels that the insurance company charges over time. Here L 2 c for any t 2 N and this premium level applies in the time period [t 1, t). Consider a general insurance surplus process of which the level of surplus at time k, k = 0, 1, . . . , is defined by U = U + (C S ) , for k 2 N , (1) 0 t t k å t=1 where S is the aggregate claims amount for time period [t 1, t) payable at time t, t 2 N ; U = u  0, u 2 N is the initial surplus level; C is the total premium for time period 0 t [t 1, t) received at time t 1 and C = L E[S ], t 2 N . Further, S has probability mass t t t t function (P.M.F.) P (s) and mean m , for J 2 R and s 2 N. S, J S, J t t The timing of all cash flows involved in the above insurance surplus process is illus- trated through the following timeline given in Figure 1 where year t denotes the period of [t 1, t), t 2 N . Risks 2021, 9, 26 5 of 23 S is paid at end of year t 1.  S is paid at the end of year t. t1 J is fixed for year t 1.  J is fixed for year t. t1 C is received at the beginning  C is received at the beginning t+1 of year t. of year t + 1. time 0 t 1 t Figure 1. The timeline of all cash flows. Given L = c and J = g, i 2 L, g 2 R, the first premium amount C can be 1 i 1 1 determined as follows C = c E[S ] = c m := a . (2) 1 i 1 i S,g i,g According to (2), theoretically a can be a non-integer value. However, an integer- i,g valued a is required for the computation of numerical results. There are two feasible i,g ways to convert non-integer a to an integer. Firstly, certain scaling-up can be applied i,g to make sure that a for all i 2 L and g 2 R are integer-valued. However, this method i,g may heavily increase the required computational time if the multiplier is a large number. Another way is to round each of a to its nearest integer, but this method potentially i,g reduces the level of accuracy in the computations. This negative impact might be minimal when considering large insurance portfolios. We remark that in this paper, we always assume that the parameters are integer-valued when necessary. In addition, all variables in our models are assumed to be integers to suit the derivations of the main recursive formulae in this paper. Non-integer valued parameters are not feasible in the recursive computational framework. The n-period finite-time ruin probability with initial surplus u, initial environment state g and initial premium level c is defined by, n 2 N , n n o y (u, n) = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g , (3) u 1 1 i,g k i k=1 where U is defined by (1) and the subscript u represents the condition U = u. By k 0 convention, for any i 2 L and g 2 R, 0 if u  0, n  0, y (u, n) = i,g 1 if u < 0, n  0. Further, we assume that the aggregate claim amounts S , t 2 N , are non-negative integer-valued random variables that follow a collective risk model structure: S = W , (4) å it i=1 where M is the total number of claims recorded in time period [t 1, t), t 2 N , with P.M.F. P (m) for J 2 R and m 2 N;fW g + , are individual claim sizes settled in time period M, J t it i2N [t 1, t). For the purpose of simplification, conditional on J , we assume that fW g + it i2N are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) with common P.M.F. P (w), w 2 N W, J and J 2 R. The claims number f M g and individual claim sizes fW g are assumed to be t t it independent of each other given J . t Risks 2021, 9, 26 6 of 23 For simplicity, we will use the symbol f to denote P (m) within the rest of this g,m M,g paper. One can show that, for s 2 N, P (s) = f P (s) S,g å g,m W,g m=0 m 0 with P (s) being the m-fold convolution of P (w) and P (0) = 1. W,g W,g W,g 2.1. Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims As introduced previously, this paper aims to consider a general bonus-malus premium system in a discrete-time setting. Let ft (s, g)g denote a general set of time- i j i,j2L;s2N;g2R homogeneous rules for premium variations, where t (s, g) = 1 if the aggregate claim i j S = s and environment state L = g lead to the transition from the premium level L = i to t t t L = j and t (s, g) = 0 otherwise. According to the definition, we have t (s, g) = 1 t+1 i j i j j=1 for any i 2 L, g 2 R, s 2 N. Let p (i, j) denote the probability that the premium level C,g,h moves from level i in initial environment state g to level j in environment state h, which can be expressed as, for any t 2 N , p (i, j) = PfL = j, J = h L = i, J = gg t t C,g,h t+1 t+1 = p (g, h) t (s, g)P (s), for i, j 2 L, g, h 2 R, (5) J å i j S,g s=0 where P (s), s 2 N, is the P.M.F. of aggregate claims in the environment state h with mean S,g m . The function t (s, g) is determined according to the given transition rule. From the S,h i j definition of p (i, j), considering a state space of f(i, g)g , its one-step transition i2L,g2R C,g,h probability matrix has the form P = [ p (i, j)] C C,g,h (lr)(lr) 2 3 p (1, 1)  p (1, l)  p (1, 1)  p (1, l) C,1,1 C,1,1 C,1,r C,1,r 6 7 . . . . . . 6 . . . . . . 7 . . . . . . 6 7 6 7 p (l, 1)  p (l, l)  p (l, 1)  p (l, l) 6 7 C,1,1 C,1,1 C,1,r C,1,r 6 7 . . . . 6 7 . . . . = . (6) 6 . . . . 7 6 7 6 p (1, 1)  p (1, l)  p (1, 1)  p (1, l)7 C,r,1 C,r,1 C,r,r C,r,r 6 7 . . . . 6 . . 7 . . . . . . 4 . . 5 . . . . p (l, 1)  p (l, l)  p (l, 1)  p (l, l) C,r,1 C,r,1 C,r,r C,r,r Note that the above matrix is constructed based on the combined statuses of pairs of premium level and environment state, which is a generalised version of the usual transition matrix for individual premium levels or transition matrix for individual environment states. The associated stationary probability distribution of P is denoted by p = [p ] , for C,g,h ig lr i 2 L and g 2 R. From (5) we have, for j 2 L, h 2 R, l r p = p p (i, j) jh å å ig C,g,h i=1 g=1 l r ¥ = p p (g, h) t (s, g)P (s). ig J i j s,g å å å i=1 g=1 s=0 Following a common practice, we would also assume that the surplus process (1) satisfies the positive safety loading conditions, for any i 2 L, g 2 R, a > m . ig S,g Risks 2021, 9, 26 7 of 23 Remark 1. The above positive safety loading condition assumption is more conservative than it usually appears in the Markov modulated risk model literature, because it needs to be in such form to enable the generalised Lundberg inequalities discussed in Section 4. 2.2. Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency When periodic premiums adjust according to the claim frequency experience rather than the aggregate claim amounts, the transition probability p in (5) needs to be C,g,h(i,j) modified as p (i, j) = p (g, h) t (m, g) f , for i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, (7) C,g,h J å i j g,m m=0 where f , for m 2 N, is the P.M.F. of the claims number in the environment state g. g,m 3. Finite-Time Ruin Probabilities In this section, we shall derive recursive formulae to compute the finite-time ruin prob- abilities that are defined by (3). We consider the two options of varying premiums separately. 3.1. Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims According to the assumptions in Section 2.1, the n-period finite-time ruin probability y (u, n), satisfies the following recursive formula. i,g Theorem 1. For u  0, n 2 N , i 2 L and g 2 R, u+a r l i,g y (u, n + 1) = p (g, h) t (s, g)y (u + a s, n)P (s) i,g å J å å i j j,h i,g S,g h=1 j=1 s=0 + P (s) (8) S,g s=u+a +1 i,g with y (u, 1) = å P (s). i,g S,g s=u+a +1 i,g Proof of Theorem 1. From (3), we have n+1 n o y (u, n + 1) = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g i,g k 1 i 1 k=1 u+a i,g n n+1 o ¥ = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g, S = s P (s) + P (s) å k 1 i 1 1 S,g å S,g s=0 s=u+c m +1 k=1 i S,h u+a i,g n n+1 o = t (s, g)P (U < 0) L = c , J = g P (s) å å i j u+a s k 2 j 1 S,g i,g j=1 s=0 k=2 + P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g u+a i,g n+1 r l n o = p (g, h) t (s, g)P (U < 0) L = c , J = h P (s) å J å å i j u+a s 2 j 2 S,g i,g k j=1 s=0 h=1 k=2 + P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g u+a r l i,g ¥ = p (g, h) t (s, g)y (u + a s, n)P (s) + P (s). å J å å i j j,h i,g S,g å S,g s=0 h=1 j=1 s=u+a +1 i,g Risks 2021, 9, 26 8 of 23 Since y (u, 1) only measures the probability of ruin of the business within one time i,g period, the verification of the given boundary condition is trivial. 3.2. Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency For this section, we change the transition rule for premium adjustment from consider- ing the aggregate claims to number of claims. According to the assumptions in Section 2.2, the n-period-finite-time ruin probability with premiums adjusted according to claims num- bers, initial premium level i and initial environment state g satisfies the following the recursive formulae. Theorem 2. For u  0, n 2 N , i 2 L and g 2 R, u+a u+a i,g i,g r l y (u, n + 1) = p (g, h) f t (m, g) P (s)y (u + a s, n) i,g å J å å g,m i j å j,h i,g W,g s=m h=1 j=1 m=0 + P (s) (9) S,g s=u+a +1 i,g with y (u, 1) = P (s). i,g å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g Proof of Theorem 2. Since the proof of Theorem 2 is largely similar to the proof of Theorem 1, we omit the details here. Its full proof can be found in Appendix A. 4. Lundberg Inequalities for Ruin Probabilities In previous sections, we studied the finite-time ruin probabilities, which reflect the risk of ruin for insurers within finite terms. However, in practice, insurers and insurance regulators also concern about the risk of ruin in the long term, where ultimate ruin proba- bilities are the appropriate measurement instead of the finite-time ones. The ultimate ruin probabilities can be defined by letting n = ¥ in (3), which is denoted by y (u), i 2 L and i,g g 2 R. Due to the general settings of premium changing rules and aggregate claim distri- butions, neither explicit results nor recursive formulae for the ultimate ruin probabilities can be obtained easily. How to extend our finite-time ruin probability recursive formulae to the infinite-time context remains an open problem for the future. Instead of calculating the ultimate ruin probabilities directly, we would derive some upper bounds for them in this section. It is inspired by the Lundberg inequality result in the classical risk model. Some Lundberg-type upper bounds, named as generalised Lundberg inequalities, are obtained with the induction method in both cases of premium variations. A similar approach was used in Cai and Dickson (2004). To calculate the generalised Lundberg inequalities, the stationary distribution p defined in Section 2.1 is needed, which represents the long-term probabilities of premium levels and environment states. We consider the case of premiums adjusted by aggregate claims first. Following the classical risk model Lundberg inequality approach, to derive an upper bound for the ultimate-time ruin probabilities, we need to find the corresponding adjustment coefficient for our generalised risk model first. Let g > 0, i 2 L, g 2 R, be constants satisfying the i,g following equation, g a g S i,g i,g i,g 1 e E e J = g = 1. (10) Then g = inf fg g is a generalised adjustment coefficient. It can be shown that, i,g i2L; g2R by the log-convexity property of the moment generating functions, for any i 2 L, g 2 R, g a g S i,g 1 e E e J = g  1. (11) We can obtain the following main result: Risks 2021, 9, 26 9 of 23 Theorem 3. Let g > 0 be the generalised adjustment coefficient defined above, then for any i 2 L, g 2 R, gu y (u)  be , (12) i,g g t ¥ e å P (s) s=t+1 S,g where b = sup . g s e P (s) S,g t0; g2R s=t+1 Proof of Theorem 3. Firstly, we need to prove by induction that for any n > 0, y (u, n) i,g gu be . When n = 1, we have, for i 2 L, g 2 R, y (u, 1) = P (s) i,g å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g g(u+a ) ¥ i,g ¥ h i e P (t) S,g t=u+a +1 i,g g(u+a ) g s i,g = e e P (s) å S,g g t e P (t) S,g t=u+a +1 s=u+a +1 i,g i,g g(u+a ) g s i,g be e P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g g a g u g S i,g 1 be e E e J = g gu be . (13) Assume the result holds true for the case of n  1, i.e., gu y (u, n)  be , i 2 L, g 2 R. i,g We only need to show that it also holds for the case of n + 1. From (8) and (13), we have u+a i,g r l y (u, n + 1) = p (g, h) t (s, g)y (u + a s, n)P (s) i,g å J å å i j j,h i,g S,g h=1 j=1 s=0 + P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g u+a i,g r l g(u+a s) i,g b e p (g, h) t (s, g)P (s) J i j S,g å å å s=0 h=1 j=1 g(u+a s) i,g +b e P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g g(u+a s) i,g = b e P (s) å S,g s=0 g u g a g S i,g = be e E e J = g gu be . By induction, we conclude that for any n > 0, gu y (u, n)  be . i,g Since y (u) = lim y (u, n), this upper bound also holds for y (u). i,g i,g i,g n!¥ Risks 2021, 9, 26 10 of 23 Remark 2. From the similarity between the recursive formulae given in Theorems 1 and 2, one can see that the Lundberg inequality (12) also applies to the ultimate ruin probabilities in the case of premiums adjusted by claims frequency. 5. The Joint Distribution of Premium Level and Environment State at Ruin In this section, given that ruin occurs, the joint distribution of the premium level and environment state at ruin is studied. 5.1. Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims Let T = min k : U < 0 U = u be the time of ruin with initial surplus u. Define u 0 c (u, n, j, h) = P T  n, L = c , J = h L = c , J = g u u T T i,g j 1 i 1 u u to be the probability that ruin occurs within the first n time periods with the premium level c and the environment state h at ruin given the initial surplus u, initial premium level i and initial environment state g, where u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R. Then, the joint probability of premium level c and environment state h at ruin given that ruin occurs within the next n periods with initial surplus u, initial premium level c and initial environment state g, denoted by c (u, n, j, h), takes the form i,g c (u, n, j, h) i,g c (u, n, j, h) = , i,g y (u, n) i,g where y (u, n) can be computed using (8). i,g A trivial relationship between c (u, n, j, h) and y (u, n) is that, for u  0, n 2 N , i,g i,g i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, l r c (u, n, j, h) = y (u, n). å å i,g i,g j=1 h=1 Parallel to Theorem 1, we can show that c (u, n, j, h) satisfies the following i,g recursive formula. Theorem 4. For u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, u+c r l c (u, n + 1, j, h) = p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h) i,g å J å S,g å i j j ,h i 0 0 s=0 h =1 j =1 + 1 1 P (s), (14) å S,g fi=jg fg=hg s=u+c +1 where c (u, 1, j, h) = 1 1 P (s). i,g S,g fi=jg fg=hg s=u+c +1 i Risks 2021, 9, 26 11 of 23 Proof of Theorem 4. Following the definition of c (u, n, j, h), we have, for u  0, n 2 N , i,g i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, c (u, n + 1, j, h) i,g n o = P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = g u u T j T 1 i 1 u u h u+c i r ¥ = p (g, h ) P (s) + P (s) J S,g S,g å å å s=0 s=u+c +1 h =1 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = h , S = s u u T j T 1 i 2 1 u u u+c ¥ r l = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g) fi=jg fg=hg å S,g å J å S,g å i j 0 0 s=u+c +1 h =1 s=0 j =1 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h , S = s u u T j T 2 j 2 1 u u u+c ¥ r l = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g) å S,g å J å S,g å i j fi=jg fg=hg 0 0 s=u+c +1 h =1 s=0 j =1 n o P T  n, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h u+c s u+c s T j T 2 j 2 i i u+c s u+c s i i r u+c l = p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h) å J å S,g å i j j ,h i 0 0 h =1 s=0 j =1 + 1 1 P (s). fi=jg fg=hg å S,g s=u+c +1 The verification of the boundary condition is trivial. 5.2. Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency The notations and definitions are same as the case of premiums adjusted according to c (u,n,j,h) i,g aggregate claims. The corresponding c (u, n, j, h) is also computed by , where i,g y (u,n) i,g y (u, n) is calculated by (9) and c (u, n, j, h) satisfied the following recursive formulae. i,g i,g Theorem 5. For u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, ¥ r u+c u+c i i 0 m c (u, n + 1, j, h) = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) g,m i,g fi=jg fg=hg å S,g å J å å W,g m=0 s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 t 0(m, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h), (15) å i j j ,h i j =1 where c (u, 1, j, h) = 1 1 P (s). i,g S,g fi=jg fg=hg s=u+c +1 Proof of Theorem 5. Since the proof of Theorem 5 is largely similar to the proof of Theorem 4, we omit the details here. Its full proof can be found in Appendix B. 6. Some Numerical Results In this section we shall provide two numerical examples that represent the two varying premium cases discussed previously in this paper and the numerical results regarding the ruin probabilities are given with some concluding remarks. Risks 2021, 9, 26 12 of 23 6.1. An Example for Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims This example is designed for the case that premiums are adjusted according to aggre- gate claims. We assume that the economic state is fixed over a year from the beginning, and the economic state affects the aggregate claims distribution in the year. It implies that the yearly aggregate claims distribution changes whenever the economic state changes. The aggregate claims are assumed to be negative binomial distributed as follows: • Economic state 1 (normal): mean = 10, variance = 101.743; • Economic state 2 (deflation): mean = 5, variance = 54.664; • Economic state 3 (inflation): mean = 15, variance = 268.187. The one-step transition probability matrix of the economic state is 2 3 0.8 0.1 0.1 4 5 P = p (g, h) = 0.3 0.65 0.05 , J J g,h=1,2,3 0.3 0.05 0.65 with stationary distribution l = [l = 0.6, l = 0.2, l = 0.2]. The expected long-term 1 2 3 aggregate claim amount is: (0.6 10) + (0.2 5) + (0.2 15) = 10. Suppose the set of premium loading is c = f120%, 140%, 160%, 180%, 200%g. The rules for adjusting the premiums are given as follows. 1. If the recorded aggregate claims in the current period is no more than the 30th per- centile of the aggregate claim distribution, then the premium level for the next period will move to the lower premium level or stay in the lowest one; 2. If the recorded aggregate claims in the current period is more than the 30th percentile but no more than the 70th percentile of the aggregate claim distribution, then the premium level for the next period will remain in the current premium level; 3. If the recorded aggregate claims in the current period is more than the 70th percentile of the aggregate claim distribution, then the premium level for the next period will move to the higher premium level or stay in the highest one. Remark 3. • The transition matrix of economic state given above is a hypothetical one. Different matrices will generate different sequences of premiums in the future. How to obtain a reliable estimate of such a transition matrix in real-life is beyond the scope of this study. Econometric studies could possibly provide answers to this question. • The above set of premium rules is again a hypothetical one and is a much simplified version of the real-life bonus-malus rules. This helps to simplify the computational process and can sufficiently showcase our key results obtained in the main text before. • The premium loadings given in c do not indicate the bonus or malus cases directly. Only when the initial premium level (or base level) is chosen, then we can tell whether a given premium level is a bonus (lower than base level) or a malus case (higher than base level). According to the above transition rule, we can calculate the transition matrix among premium levels, i.e., P = [ p (i, j)] , defined in (6) in Appendix C. Using C,g,h (lr)(lr) P , we can find the long-term stationary joint distribution of the premium levels and economics conditions: 2 3 0.1270, 0.1234, 0.1199, 0.1165, 0.1132 4 5 p = [p ] = 0.0421, 0.0411, 0.0400, 0.0389, 0.0379 . ig i2L,g2R 0.0424, 0.0411, 0.0400, 0.0388, 0.0377 The expected long-term premium income calculated from p is 15.89 per time unit, which is roughly 60% greater than the expected long-term aggregate claim amount per time unit. Assuming the initial economic state is 1 (normal condition), using (8) we calculate Risks 2021, 9, 26 13 of 23 the finite-time ruin probabilities y (u, 40), i = 1, . . . , 5, and the associated Lundberg upper i1 bounds for the ultimate ruin probabilities y (u) can be found using (12). These results are ig summarised in Table 1 and Figure 2 below. As shown in Table 1 and Figure 2, one can see that y (u, 40), i = 1, . . . , 5 are ordered i1 by their initial premium levels, the lower the initial premium level is, the higher the finite-time ruin probabilities. Secondly, the initial surplus level u has a significant impact on differentiating the five finite-time ruin probabilities: these probabilities differ more from each other when u is small, but this impact tends to wear off when u becomes larger. For example, for u = 0, y (0, 40) = 0.581516, whereas y (0, 40) = 0.220787 1,1 5,1 (around 0.36 in difference). On the other hand, for u = 50, y (50, 40) = 0.039369 and 1,1 y (50, 40) = 0.007212 (only 0.03 in difference). Its implications coincide with the practical 5,1 concerns when choosing the initial premium level with different u levels: a low initial premium level tends to be very risky when u is small. However, when the initial surplus u is sufficiently large, the insurer has more flexibility to lower the initial premium level that can attract more new policyholders and help with boosting the insurance business without significantly increasing the risk of insolvency. One obvious observation in Figure 2 regarding the upper bound is that it is very loose for all five versions of finite-time ruin probabilities. An argument for this is that the generalised adjustment coefficient g adopted in (12) is quite conservative, since it is determined by the scenario that has the highest ruin probabilities by its definition. Also, the upper bound given in (12) is for the ultimate time ruin probabilities, so tend to be fairly loose for finite-time ruin probabilities with n = 40. In practice, the insurer can use these upper bounds to evaluate the worst-scenario risk of ruin in the long run. Table 1. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,1 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,1 2,1 3,1 4,1 5,1 0 0.581516 0.485600 0.370290 0.278787 0.220787 0.982500 10 0.346148 0.268051 0.189482 0.135426 0.106381 0.823486 20 0.202262 0.147489 0.097952 0.067067 0.052281 0.690207 30 0.117224 0.081516 0.051458 0.034011 0.026317 0.578500 40 0.067836 0.045466 0.027558 0.017698 0.013597 0.484872 50 0.039369 0.025658 0.015062 0.009450 0.007212 0.406397 70 0.013508 0.008491 0.004769 0.002893 0.002181 0.285494 90 0.004775 0.002943 0.001609 0.000954 0.000713 0.200560 120 0.001052 0.000638 0.000340 0.000197 0.000146 0.118091 150 0.000240 0.000144 0.000075 0.000043 0.000031 0.069532 200 0.000021 0.000012 0.000006 0.000004 0.000003 0.028761 First of all, given each initial economic state, we make similar observations in the trending in finite-time ruin probabilities when u and i change. Following that, comparing the three cases with different initial economic states, we have some interesting findings. Firstly, when u = 0 and three i cases of u = 10, the deflation economic state (state 2) leads to the highest finite-time ruin probabilities whilst the inflation economic state (state 3) has the lowest finite-time ruin probabilities. Secondly, when the initial premium level is at the lowest one (i = 1) and u  10, the inflation economic state leads to the highest ruin probabilities whilst the deflation state has the lowest ones. For remaining cases, the inflation state usually ranks the highest in finite-time ruin probabilities and the normal economic state ranks the lowest. We struggle to find intuitive reasons behind these observations. One contributing factor is the initial premium amount. The ranking of ruin probabilities when u = 0 coincides with the ranking of the initial premium amounts correspond to the three initial economic states, which again confirms the significant role of the early premium income in keeping solvency when there is no capital buffer in the first place. Based on these observations, it is fair to say that both initial economic state and initial premium level play important roles in determining the finite-time ruin probabilities of the insurance business. Therefore, the insurers must keep a close eye on this matter when optimising Risks 2021, 9, 26 14 of 23 their premium-changing strategies. Next, we shall dig further into the relationship between u, the premium level and economic state at ruin given ruin occurs. As an example, we calculate the joint distribution of the premium level and economic state at ruin given the ruin occurs within 10 periods, i.e., c (0, 10, j, h), making use of the result (14). i,g y (u, 40) 1,1 0.9 y (u, 40) 2,1 0.8 y (u, 40) 3,1 0.7 y (u, 40) 4,1 y (u, 40) 0.6 5,1 UB 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 40 80 120 160 200 Figure 2. y (u, 40) with the upper bounds. i,1 For the initial economics state 2 (deflation condition) and state 3 (inflation condition), the finite-time ruin probability results are given in Tables 2 and 3, respectively. Table 2. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,2 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,2 2,2 3,2 4,2 5,2 0 0.602651 0.530232 0.432010 0.346695 0.290467 0.982500 10 0.340618 0.280003 0.210953 0.159843 0.132489 0.823486 20 0.194130 0.151662 0.107550 0.077895 0.063776 0.690207 30 0.110690 0.083187 0.056257 0.039292 0.031786 0.578500 40 0.063296 0.046186 0.030090 0.020401 0.016316 0.484872 50 0.036402 0.025979 0.016437 0.010875 0.008605 0.406397 70 0.012333 0.008554 0.005196 0.003313 0.002573 0.285494 90 0.004325 0.002954 0.001750 0.001087 0.000832 0.200560 120 0.000946 0.000638 0.000369 0.000223 0.000168 0.118091 150 0.000215 0.000143 0.000082 0.000049 0.000036 0.069532 200 0.000019 0.000012 0.000007 0.000004 0.000003 0.028761 In Table 4, c (0, 10, 1, 1) is the highest one among all 15 cases, much larger than 1,1 all the other cases. It means that, given that u = 0 and ruin occurs by time 10, the most likely premium level and economic state combination at ruin is the same as the initial combination (i = 1, g = 1). The second and third most likely cases are (j = 2, h = 1) and (j = 1, h = 3) that are adjacent combinations of (i = 1, g = 1). This implies that without any capital buffer at the beginning and charging the lowest level of premium, if ruin occurs early, then it will occur within the first few time units before making many transitions in either premium levels or economic states. Of course, the initial premium level and initial economic state as well as u all play an important roles in this. We shall continue this investigation in our next scenario. Risks 2021, 9, 26 15 of 23 Table 3. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,3 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,3 2,3 3,3 4,3 5,3 0 0.536216 0.441881 0.338071 0.259681 0.209647 0.982500 10 0.362565 0.284586 0.209476 0.157582 0.127362 0.823486 20 0.240562 0.181306 0.129259 0.095593 0.077312 0.690207 30 0.157427 0.114621 0.079529 0.057972 0.046900 0.578500 40 0.101979 0.072065 0.048833 0.035150 0.028439 0.484872 50 0.065557 0.045126 0.029942 0.021312 0.017240 0.406397 70 0.026650 0.017546 0.011225 0.007835 0.006334 0.285494 90 0.010669 0.006769 0.004198 0.002881 0.002327 0.200560 120 0.002651 0.001606 0.000957 0.000643 0.000519 0.118091 150 0.000647 0.000377 0.000217 0.000144 0.000116 0.069532 200 0.000060 0.000033 0.000018 0.000012 0.000009 0.028761 Scenario 1. Let u = 0, i = 1 and g = 1. Values of c (0, 10, j, h) are summarised in Table 4. 1,1 Table 4. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.758260 0.066721 0.017378 0.004019 0.000892 h = 2 0.031033 0.015421 0.005128 0.001372 0.000344 h = 3 0.062983 0.026394 0.007770 0.001865 0.000421 Scenario 2. Keep u and g unchanged, but let i = 5, the highest level of premium. The correspond- ing results are given in Table 5. Table 5. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 5,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.000113 0.000726 0.004665 0.047550 0.800367 h = 2 0.000037 0.000231 0.001394 0.008976 0.038254 h = 3 0.000408 0.001594 0.005976 0.024634 0.065076 In Table 5, c (0, 10, 5, 1) is the highest one among all 15 cases, much larger than all 5,1 the others. Again, given that u = 0 and ruin occurs by time 10, the most likely premium level and economic state combination at ruin is the same as the initial combination. The second and third most likely cases are (j = 5, h = 3) and (j = 4, h = 1), the adjacent combinations of (i = 5, g = 1). It looks like when u = 0, even charging the given highest level of premium, if we know ruin occurs early, then it will still occur within the first few time units. This is a similar observation to Scenario 1. This implies that, under our model assumptions, the initial surplus plays a more important role in the insolvency risk than the initial premium level. For the purpose of comparison, we shall consider one more scenario of u = 100 to see any different observations from the u = 0 scenarios. Scenario 3. Let u = 100, i = 1 and g = 1. The corresponding results are given in Table 6. Table 6. Results for c (100, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.016169 0.053910 0.071874 0.054714 0.043763 h = 2 0.002011 0.008437 0.013755 0.012849 0.012611 h = 3 0.098078 0.218514 0.204083 0.118145 0.071086 Risks 2021, 9, 26 16 of 23 In contrast to the previous two scenarios, in Table 6, the top four most likely com- binations of premium level and economic state at ruin are (j = 2, h = 3), (j = 3, h = 3), (j = 4, h = 3), and (j = 1, h = 3). It implies that when the initial surplus is large, given ruin occurs, then ruin would most likely occur under the worst economic state, i.e., h = 3, which by assumption has the highest expected aggregate claim amount per time unit. Again, the premium level at ruin seems relatively less influential than the economic state regarding insolvency. Moreover, the values of c (100, 10, j, h) in Table 6 are more evenly spread out 1,1 than the results in Tables 4 and 5. This is because with u = 100, there are more chances that the insurance business could stay solvent in the first few periods and ruin would occur later. The longer the surplus process runs, then the less predictable it is, thus the premium level and economic state combination at ruin. 6.2. An Example for Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency In this example, we shall consider automobile insurance business and we replace the external economic environment by weather conditions. We assume that the premium levels are adjusted according to the claim frequency and the weather condition has a significant impact on the claim frequency of automobile insurance policyholders. • The claim frequency is modelled by Poisson distribution with mean 1.57, 0.785 and 2.355 for weather state 1 (normal condition), 2 (less severe condition) and 3 (severe weather condition) respectively. • The one-step transition probability matrix of weather states (environment state) with the corresponding stationary probability distribution are the same as the ones for the external economic states in the previous example. Similar to the previous example, the weather state is assumed to be fixed over a year from the beginning and the premiums depend on the current weather state. • The individual claim size distribution under each weather state is assumed to be 1.57 1.57 (w1) 10 geometric with P.M.F. P (w) = ( )(1 ) for w  1 and mean . Then 10 10 1.57 the expected aggregate claim amount under weather state 1, 2, and 3 is 10, 5 and 15, respectively. The expected long-term aggregate claim amount is 10, which is the same as the one in the previous example as well. We continue to use the same set of premium loading as the one in the previous example, i.e., c = f120%, 140%, 160%, 180%, 200%g. The rules for adjusting premiums are given as follows: 1. If the number of claims in the current period is 0, then the premium level for the next period will move to the lower premium level or stay in the lowest one; 2. If the number of claims in the current period is greater than 0 but no more than 2, then the premium level for the next period will remain in the current premium level; 3. If the number of claims in the current period is more 2, then the premium level for the next period will move to the higher premium level or stay in the highest one. According to the above transition rules for premium adjustments, we can also find its associated transition matrix among the premium levels in the Appendix D, and the following long-term stationary joint distribution of the premium levels and weather states: 2 3 0.1429, 0.1214, 0.1119, 0.1089, 0.1150 4 5 p = [p ] = 0.0702, 0.0394, 0.0350, 0.0314, 0.0241 . ig i2L,g2R 0.0328, 0.0374, 0.0373, 0.0380, 0.0545 Using p, one can see that the expected long-term premium is around 15.9 per time unit, which is about 60% greater than the expected long-term aggregate claims per time unit. Remarkably, the expected long-term premium loading in this example is comparable to the one in the previous example. We make the expected long-term premium income and expected long-term aggregate claims of these two examples comparable on purpose such that a comparison is feasible between the two different types of premium transition Risks 2021, 9, 26 17 of 23 rules regarding their impact on the ruin probabilities. Similarly, in the following we use the result (9) to calculate y (u, 40) and use (12) to calculate the upper bounds for the ultimate i,1 time ruin probabilities y (u). The results are summarised in Table 7 and Figure 3 below. i,1 Table 7. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,1 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,1 2,1 3,1 4,1 5,1 0 0.605971 0.509785 0.394719 0.299570 0.235311 0.971992 10 0.388786 0.299805 0.209603 0.146053 0.110407 0.731630 20 0.236054 0.167432 0.106238 0.068367 0.050195 0.550706 30 0.137875 0.090424 0.052377 0.031307 0.022445 0.414523 40 0.078166 0.047692 0.025389 0.014180 0.009959 0.312016 50 0.043249 0.024708 0.012176 0.006393 0.004407 0.234858 70 0.012487 0.006372 0.002750 0.001299 0.000865 0.133065 90 0.003391 0.001581 0.000614 0.000266 0.000172 0.075391 120 0.000441 0.000186 0.000064 0.000025 0.000015 0.032152 150 0.000053 0.000021 0.000007 0.000002 0.000001 0.013712 200 0.000001 0.000001 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.003313 y (u, 40) 1,1 0.9 y (u, 40) 2,1 0.8 y (u, 40) 3,1 0.7 y (u, 40) 4,1 0.6 y (u, 40) 5,1 UB 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 40 80 120 160 200 Figure 3. y (u, 40) with the upper bounds. i,1 Firstly, our main findings in Table 7 and Figure 3 are consistent with those in Table 1 and Figure 2 in terms of the impact of the initial premium level and initial surplus level on ruin probabilities. Secondly, given the same initial external environment state, when u is small the premium adjustment rules based on claim frequency have a negative impact on the finite-time ruin probabilities comparing with the rules by aggregate claim amounts. Also, this effect becomes more significant when the initial premium level is lower. For instance when i = 1 this effect applies to u  50 but it only takes effect for u  20 when i = 5. This is reasonable since the transition rules that adjust the premiums according to the claim frequency can not fully reflect the historical claims experience, which causes higher risk of ruin when u is small. On the contrary, when u is large enough, the premium rules by claim frequency seems to lower the insolvency risk of the insurer comparing with the other type of rules. This implies that, in practice, the insurers should carefully design their bonus-malus rules by taking into account factors like the capital adequacy level since the proposed rules could have significant impact on insolvency risk. Next, we shall investigate the finite-time ruin probabilities with initial weather state 2 and 3, which are shown in Tables 8 and 9. Risks 2021, 9, 26 18 of 23 Table 8. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,2 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,2 2,2 3,2 4,2 5,2 0 0.647608 0.600217 0.511647 0.414121 0.332302 0.971992 10 0.410970 0.362287 0.281517 0.204813 0.150624 0.731630 20 0.251122 0.211238 0.150889 0.099501 0.067739 0.550706 30 0.148774 0.119900 0.079446 0.047947 0.030482 0.414523 40 0.085828 0.066553 0.041270 0.023024 0.013769 0.312016 50 0.048375 0.036238 0.021204 0.011040 0.006249 0.234858 70 0.014483 0.010237 0.005448 0.002533 0.001305 0.133065 90 0.004064 0.002744 0.001359 0.000580 0.000276 0.075391 120 0.000550 0.000353 0.000162 0.000063 0.000027 0.032152 150 0.000069 0.000042 0.000018 0.000007 0.000003 0.013712 200 0.000002 0.000001 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.003313 Table 9. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,3 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,3 2,3 3,3 4,3 5,3 0 0.555437 0.430304 0.315517 0.231635 0.179284 0.971992 10 0.354335 0.249205 0.167191 0.115193 0.087273 0.731630 20 0.212928 0.136511 0.084156 0.054739 0.040872 0.550706 30 0.122699 0.072029 0.040953 0.025268 0.018672 0.414523 40 0.068509 0.037011 0.019486 0.011455 0.008399 0.312016 50 0.037306 0.018650 0.009134 0.005138 0.003744 0.234858 70 0.010434 0.004543 0.001955 0.001019 0.000736 0.133065 90 0.002749 0.001066 0.000411 0.000202 0.000144 0.075391 120 0.000343 0.000116 0.000039 0.000018 0.000013 0.032152 150 0.000040 0.000012 0.000004 0.000002 0.000001 0.013712 200 0.000001 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.003313 According to the results in Tables 8 and 9, the trending of finite-time ruin probabilities when u and i change is still consistent with Table 7. In contrast to the previous premium- changing category (by aggregate claims), when the premiums change according to claim frequency experience, there is an overall consistent ranking in the finite-time ruin probabil- ities among the three initial weather conditions, i.e., less severe initial weather condition (state 2) leads to the highest ruin probabilities whilst the severe initial weather condition (state 3) has the lowest ruin probabilities. This ranking can be explained by the level of right-skewness of the Compound Poisson distributions corresponding to the aggregate claims under each weather condition. Apparently, state 2 has the highest right-skewness whilst state 3 has the lowest, which relates to the risk of insolvency. At last, we shall use the (15) to compute the joint distribution of the premium level and weather condition at ruin given ruin occurs within 10 time periods. The results are given in Tables 10–12, where the scenarios considered are the same as Scenario 1–3 in the previous example. Table 10. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.788065 0.069503 0.012257 0.002256 0.000437 h = 2 0.041473 0.010975 0.002007 0.000384 0.000077 h = 3 0.045738 0.020304 0.005216 0.001088 0.000220 Risks 2021, 9, 26 19 of 23 Table 11. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 5,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.000410 0.001394 0.005025 0.039455 0.863448 h = 2 0.000204 0.000681 0.002484 0.010320 0.034591 h = 3 0.000116 0.000389 0.001216 0.006851 0.033414 Table 12. Results for c (100, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.066714 0.193377 0.205458 0.115465 0.057055 h = 2 0.017125 0.033472 0.034556 0.020260 0.010142 h = 3 0.020572 0.071252 0.082757 0.047871 0.023924 From Tables 10 and 11, one can see that under Scenario 1 and Scenario 2 (both with u = 0) we get similar main findings to those in the previous example. It is worth noting that in Scenario 3 where u = 100, we get opposite findings comparing with our previous example. The top four most likely combinations of premium level and weather conditions at ruin are (j = 3, h = 1), (j = 2, h = 1), (j = 4, h = 1) and (j = 3, h = 3), mostly associated with the normal weather conditions under which the claim experience should be the middle one. This is totally different from the previous example where in Scenario 3 the most likely combinations come from the worst economic state under which the claim experience is the worst. The most likely explanation lies in the way premiums are being adjusted as well as the claim experience assumptions under different weather conditions. To be more specific, we assume that individual claim amounts are not affected by weather conditions, but claim frequency does. Under the normal weather condition (i = 1), the current premium level is likely to stay unchanged. However, under severe weather condition (i = 3), average claim frequency is high, which leads to moving the next premium level up. To a certain extent, the worsened claim experience is off-set by the increased premium amount, which leads to a lower overall insolvency risk than the normal weather condition. We remark that this observation might not hold when the parameter assumptions are changed, which result in a different trade-off between the claim experience and premium adjustment. Last but not least, we make a further comparison between the above two numerical examples, as the risk models constructed in those two examples are in general comparable, for example, equal average aggregate claim amounts as well as the same premium levels. We can see that the case of adjusting premiums according to claim frequency is riskier than the case of adjusting premiums according to aggregate claims under our assumptions. This finding also has some material implication for the insurance companies on how to choose an appropriate premium adjustment strategy. 7. Conclusions and Discussions In this paper we considered a discrete-time risk model, which allows the premium to be adjusted according to claims experience. The premium correction was based on the well-known bonus-malus system and the claims experience was assumed to depend on an external Markovian environment (economic and/or natural environment). As a result, the evaluation of this unusual bonus-malus framework, which has non-homogeneous premium transition rules, became the main objective of this paper. To have a better coverage, two types of premium changing criteria were examined throughout the paper: aggregate claims criterion vs. claim frequency criterion. The basis of our evaluation is the risk of ruin for the proposed risk model with the given set of initial parameters, i.e., initial surplus, initial premium level and initial environment state. On the one hand, recursive formulae were obtained to calculate the finite-time ruin probabilities and Lundberg-type upper bounds were derived to evaluate the ultimate ruin probabilities in both cases. On the other hand, the joint distribution of premium level and environment state at ruin was also studied. Risks 2021, 9, 26 20 of 23 Through our numerical studies, we find that both the initial premium level and the initial environment state have a significant impact on the insolvency risk. We observed that there is no straightforward ordering on the insolvency risk among cases with different initial environmental state, which can be seen as the consequence of a combined effect of non-homogeneous loss distributions, premium rule assumptions as well as the initial surplus level. This shed a light on the importance of determining the proper base premium level in a given external environment when insurers implement the bonus-malus system in premium corrections. This paper focused on the ruin probabilities when evaluating the proposed bonus- malus system within a Markovian environment. However, how to implement the premium corrections in real life based on the main findings in this paper remains a very challenging task, as there will be no fixed premium changing rules when the external environment changes. A possible solution is that the insurer designs a special scoring system and uses it to evaluate its policyholders’ claim experience. For instance, at the end of each policy year a policyholder receives a certain score based on the ordering of his/her claim experience in the whole insurance portfolio, and then a bonus or malus can be offered in the renewal premium based on the scores. This type of score-based premium rules can effectively address the impact of external environment on premium corrections. This non-standard premium correction practice needs to be carefully communicated with the policyholders in practice. There are some limitations in the above study that are worth addressing in the future research. Firstly, the two numerical examples given above were based on a number of assumptions, including aggregate claims distribution, claim frequency distribution, transi- tion rules for premium adjustment, number of premium levels and the specific external environment processes. Whether or not these assumptions hold in real practice need to be verified and more appropriate assumptions may be required to improve the model results. Secondly, in real life the parameters associated with the assumptions need to be estimated using real-life data. For instance, we used hypothetical transition probabilities among different environment states in both our numerical examples, but in real life these probabil- ities need to be estimated using real-life economic data or meteorological data. Moreover, if the environment-initiated non-homogeneity does exhibit in the claim experiences, then the claim frequency and claim severity modelling would become more complicated and generally long-term data would be needed to obtain reliable parameter estimates. Another potential future research could be constructing a continuous-time risk model with the same features as the discrete-time model in this paper. Then we could study the impact of the bonus-malus system and the external Markovian environment on the ultimate-time ruin probability. Author Contributions: Conceptualization, D.O. and X.W.; methodology, D.O. and X.W.; numerical analysis, D.O.; writing–original draft preparation, D.O.; writing–review and editing, X.W.; supervi- sion, X.W.; All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript. Funding: Dhiti Osatakul is supported by the Faculty of Business and Economics studentship by The University of Melbourne and the Chulalongkorn University Scholarship. Acknowledgments: The authors are very grateful to the three anonymous reviewers whose construc- tive comments have led to substantial improvements of this paper. Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest. Risks 2021, 9, 26 21 of 23 Appendix A Proof of Theorem 2. From (3), we have, for u  0, n 2 N , i 2 L and g 2 R, n+1 n o y (u, n + 1) = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g i,g k 1 i 1 k=1 n+1 ¥ ¥ n o = f P (s)P (U < 0) L = c , J = g, S = s å g,m å u k 1 i 1 1 W,g m=0 s=0 k=1 ¥ ¥ = f P (s) å g,m å W,g m=0 s=u+a +1 i,g u+a i,g n+1 r n o + p (g, h) P (s)P (U < 0) L = c , J = h, S = s u 2 å J å W,g k 1 i 1 h=1 s=0 k=1 u+a u+a i,g i,g ¥ r l = P (s) + p (g, h) f t (m, g) P (s) J g,m å S,g å å å i j å W,g s=m s=u+a +1 h=1 j=1 m=0 i,g n+1 n o P (U < 0) L = c , J = h u+a s 2 2 k j i,g k=2 u+a u+a i,g i,g r l = p (g, h) f t (m, g) P (s)y (u + a s, n) J g,m å å å i j å W,g j,h i,g s=m h=1 j=1 m=0 + P (s). å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g Again, since y (u, 1) only measures the probability of ruin of the business within one time i,g period, the verification of the given boundary condition is trivial. Appendix B Proof of Theorem 5. Similar to the proof of Theorem 4, we have, for u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, c (u, n + 1, j, h) i,g n o = P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = g u u T j T 1 i 1 u u r ¥ ¥ 0 m = p (g, h ) f P (s) g,m å J å å W,g m=0 s=0 h =1 P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = h , S = s u u T j T 1 i 2 1 u u u+c u+c ¥ r i i 0 m = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) S,g J g,m fi=jg fg=hg å å å å W,g s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 m=0 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = h , S = s u u T j T 1 i 2 1 u u u+c u+c ¥ r i i l 0 m = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) t 0(m, g) S,g J g,m fi=jg fg=hg å å å å W,g å i j 0 0 s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 m=0 j =1 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h , S = s u u T T 2 2 u j u j 1 ¥ r u+c u+c l i i 0 m = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) t 0(m, g) å S,g å J å g,m å å i j fi=jg fg=hg W,g 0 0 m=0 s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 j =1 n o P T  n, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h u+c s u+c s T j T 2 j 2 i i u+c s u+c s i i u+c u+c r l i i 0 m = p (g, h ) f P (s) t 0(m, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h) g,m å J å å W,g å i j j ,h i 0 s=m 0 h =1 m=0 j =1 + 1 1 P (s). fi=jg fg=hg å S,g s=u+c +1 i Risks 2021, 9, 26 22 of 23 The verification of the boundary condition is trivial. Appendix C The transition matrix among premium levels in Section 6.1. P = [ p (i, j)] C C,g,h (lr)(lr) 2 3 0.5668 0.2332 0 0 0 0.0709 0.0291 0 0 0 0.0709 0.0291 0 0 0 60.2405 0.3263 0.2332 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 7 6 7 6 0 0.2405 0.3263 0.2332 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 7 6 7 0 0 0.2405 0.3263 0.2332 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.2405 0.5595 0 0 0 0.0301 0.0699 0 0 0 0.0301 0.06997 6 7 60.2114 0.0886 0 0 0 0.4581 0.1919 0 0 0 0.0352 0.0148 0 0 0 7 6 7 0.0900 0.1214 0.0886 0 0 0.1950 0.2631 0.1919 0 0 0.0150 0.0202 0.0148 0 0 6 7 6 7 =6 0 0.0900 0.1214 0.0886 0 0 0.1950 0.2631 0.1919 0 0 0.0150 0.0202 0.0148 0 7. 6 7 0 0 0.0900 0.1214 0.0886 0 0 0.1950 0.2631 0.1919 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.0900 0.2100 0 0 0 0.1950 0.4550 0 0 0 0.0150 0.03507 6 7 60.2129 0.0871 0 0 0 0.0355 0.0145 0 0 0 0.4613 0.1887 0 0 0 7 6 7 0.0900 0.1229 0.0871 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 0 0 0.1950 0.2663 0.1887 0 0 6 7 6 7 6 0 0.0900 0.1229 0.0871 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 0 0 0.1950 0.2663 0.1887 0 7 4 5 0 0 0.0900 0.1229 0.0871 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 0 0 0.1950 0.2663 0.1887 0 0 0 0.0900 0.2100 0 0 0 0.0150 0.0350 0 0 0 0.1950 0.4550 Appendix D The transition matrix among premium levels in Section 6.2. P = [ p (i, j)] C C,g,h (lr)(lr) 2 3 0.6329 0.1671 0 0 0 0.0791 0.0209 0 0 0 0.0791 0.0209 0 0 0 60.1664 0.4664 0.1671 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 7 6 7 0 0.1664 0.4664 0.1671 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0.1664 0.4664 0.1671 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.02097 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.1664 0.6336 0 0 0 0.0208 0.0792 0 0 0 0.0208 0.07927 6 7 0.2864 0.0136 0 0 0 0.6206 0.0294 0 0 0 0.0477 0.0023 0 0 0 6 7 6 7 60.1368 0.1496 0.0136 0 0 0.2965 0.3241 0.0294 0 0 0.0228 0.0249 0.0023 0 0 7 6 7 =6 0 0.1368 0.1496 0.0136 0 0 0.2965 0.3241 0.0294 0 0 0.0228 0.0249 0.0023 0 7. 6 7 0 0 0.1368 0.1496 0.0136 0 0 0.2965 0.3241 0.0294 0 0 0.0228 0.0249 0.0023 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.1368 0.1632 0 0 0 0.2965 0.3535 0 0 0 0.0228 0.02727 6 7 0.1745 0.1255 0 0 0 0.0291 0.0209 0 0 0 0.3780 0.2720 0 0 0 6 7 6 7 0.0285 0.1460 0.1255 0 0 0.0047 0.0243 0.0209 0 0 0.0617 0.3163 0.2720 0 0 6 7 6 7 6 0 0.0285 0.1460 0.1255 0 0 0.0047 0.0243 0.0209 0 0 0.0617 0.3163 0.2720 0 7 4 5 0 0 0.0285 0.1460 0.1255 0 0 0.0047 0.0243 0.0209 0 0 0.0617 0.3163 0.2720 0 0 0 0.0285 0.2715 0 0 0 0.0047 0.0453 0 0 0 0.0617 0.5883 References Afonso, Lourdes B., Alfredo D. Egidio dos Reis, and Howard R. Waters. 2009. Calculating continuous time ruin probabilities for a large portfolio with varying premiums. ASTIN Bulletin 39: 117–36. [CrossRef] Afonso, Lourdes B., Rui M. R. Cardoso, Alfredo D. Egídio dos Reis, and Gracinda R. Guerreiro. 2020. Ruin Probabilities And Capital Requirement for Open Automobile Portfolios With a Bonus-Malus System Based on Claim Counts. Journal of Risk and Insurance 87: 501–22. [CrossRef] Afonso, Lourdes B., Rui M. R. Cardoso, Gracinda R. Guerreiro, and Alfredo D. Egídio dos Reis. 2017. Measuring the impact of a Bonus-Malus system in finite and continuous time ruin probabilities for large portfolios in motor insurance. ASTIN Bulletin 47: 417–35. [CrossRef] Ágoston, Kolos C., and Márton Gyetvai. 2020. Joint optimization of transition rules and the premium scale in a bonus-malus system. ASTIN Bulletin 50: 743–76. [CrossRef] Baione, Fabio, Susanna Levantesi, and Massimiliano Menzietti. 2002. The Development of an Optimal Bonus-Malus System in a Competitive Market. ASTIN Bulletin 32: 159–70. [CrossRef] Cai, Jun, and David M. Dickson. 2004. Ruin probabilities with a Markov chain interest model. Insurance: Mathematics & Economics 35: 513–25. Constantinescu, Corina, Suhang Dai, Weihong Ni, and Zbigniew Palmowski. 2016. Ruin probabilities with dependence on the number of claims within a fixed time window. Risks 4: 17. [CrossRef] Risks 2021, 9, 26 23 of 23 Denuit, Michel, Montserrat Guillen, and Julien Trufin. 2019. Multivariate credibility modelling for usage-based motor insurance pricing with behavioural data. Annals of Actuarial Science 13: 378–99. [CrossRef] De Pril, Nelson. 1979. Optimal Claim Decisions for a Bonus-Malus System: A Continuous Approach. ASTIN Bulletin 10: 215–22. [CrossRef] Dionne, Georges, and Olfa N. Ghali. 2005. The (1992) Bonus-Malus System in Tunisia: An Empirical Evaluation. Journal of Risk and Insurance 72: 609–33. [CrossRef] Dufresne, Par Francois. 1988. Distributions stationnaires d’un système bonus–malus et probabilité de ruine. ASTIN Bulletin 18: 31–46. [CrossRef] Kucer ˇ ovský, Dan, and Amir P. Najafabadi. 2017. Solving an Integral Equation Arising from the Ruin Probability of Long-term Bonus-Malus Systems. Available online: https://arxiv.org/abs/1701.05570 (accessed on 1 September 2020). Lee, Bong-Joo, and Dae-Hwan Kim. 2016. Moral Hazard in Insurance Claiming from a Korean Natural Experiment. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance: Issues and Practice 41: 455–67. [CrossRef] Lemaire, Jean. 1995. Bonus-Malus Systems in Automobile Insurances. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Lemaire, Jean, and Hongmin Zi. 1994. A Comparative Analysis of 30 Bonus-Malus Systems. ASTIN Bulletin 24: 287–309. [CrossRef] Li, Bo, Weihong Ni, and Corina Constantinescu. 2015. Risk models with premiums adjusted to claims number. Insurance: Mathematics & Economics 65: 94–102. Li, Jingchao, and Shuanming Li. 2020. Some State-Specific Exit Probabilities in a Markov-Modulated Risk Model. Mathematical Problems in Engineering 2020: 5830245. [CrossRef] Nie, Changwei, Mi Chen, and Haiyan Liu. 2020. On a Discrete Markov-Modulated Risk Model with Random Premium Income and Delayed Claims. Mathematical Problems in Engineering 2020: 3042543. [CrossRef] Niemiec, Malgorzata. 2007. Bonus-Malus Systems as Markov Set-chains. ASTIN Bulletin 37: 53–65. [CrossRef] Park, Sojung C., Jean Lemaire, and Choong Tze Chua. 2010. Is the design of bonus-malus systems influenced by insurance maturity or national culture? Evidence from Asia. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance: Issues and Practice 35: S7–S27. [CrossRef] Pinquet, Jean, Montserrat Guillén, and Catalina Bolancé. 2001. Allowance for the Age of Claims in Bonus-Malus Systems. ASTIN Bulletin 31: 337–48. [CrossRef] Pitrebois, Sandra, Michel Denuit, and Jean-Francois Walhin. 2006. Multi-Event Bonus-Malus Scales. Journal of Risk and Insurance 73: 517–28. [CrossRef] Trufin, Julien, and Stéphane Loisel. 2013. Ultimate ruin probability in discrete time with Bühlmann credibility premium adjustments. Bulletin Franais d’Actuariat 13: 73–102. Vilar-Zanón, José L., Antonio Heras, and Estela de Frutos. 2020. An average model approach to experience based premium rates discounts: An application to Spanish agricultural insurance. European Actuarial Journal 10: 361–75. [CrossRef] Viswanathan, Krupa, and Jean Lemaire. 2005. Bonus-malus Systems in a Deregulated Environment: Forecasting Market Shares Using Diffusion Models. ASTIN Bulletin 35: 299–319. [CrossRef] Wagner, Christian. 2002. Time in the red in a two state markov model. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 31: 365–72. [CrossRef] Wu, Xueyuan, Mi Chen, Junyi Guo, and Can Jin. 2015. On a discrete-time risk model with claim correlated premiums. Annals of Actuarial Science 9: 322–42. [CrossRef] http://www.deepdyve.com/assets/images/DeepDyve-Logo-lg.png Risks Multidisciplinary Digital Publishing Institute

Discrete-Time Risk Models with Claim Correlated Premiums in a Markovian Environment

Risks , Volume 9 (1) – Jan 14, 2021

Loading next page...
 
/lp/multidisciplinary-digital-publishing-institute/discrete-time-risk-models-with-claim-correlated-premiums-in-a-4ZPNpwDENs

References

References for this paper are not available at this time. We will be adding them shortly, thank you for your patience.

Publisher
Multidisciplinary Digital Publishing Institute
Copyright
© 1996-2021 MDPI (Basel, Switzerland) unless otherwise stated Disclaimer The statements, opinions and data contained in the journals are solely those of the individual authors and contributors and not of the publisher and the editor(s). MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. Terms and Conditions Privacy Policy
ISSN
2227-9091
DOI
10.3390/risks9010026
Publisher site
See Article on Publisher Site

Abstract

risks Article Discrete-Time Risk Models with Claim Correlated Premiums in a Markovian Environment † ,† Dhiti Osatakul and Xueyuan Wu * Department of Economics, The University of Melbourne, Parkville, VIC 3010, Australia; dosatakul@student.unimelb.edu.au * Correspondence: xueyuanw@unimelb.edu.au; Tel.: +61-3-83447939 † These authors contributed equally to this work. Abstract: In this paper we consider a discrete-time risk model, which allows the premium to be adjusted according to claims experience. This model is inspired by the well-known bonus- malus system in the non-life insurance industry. Two strategies of adjusting periodic premiums are considered: aggregate claims or claim frequency. Recursive formulae are derived to compute the finite-time ruin probabilities, and Lundberg-type upper bounds are also derived to evaluate the ultimate-time ruin probabilities. In addition, we extend the risk model by considering an external Markovian environment in which the claims distributions are governed by an external Markov process so that the periodic premium adjustments vary when the external environment state changes. We then study the joint distribution of premium level and environment state at ruin given ruin occurs. Two numerical examples are provided at the end of this paper to illustrate the impact of the initial external environment state, the initial premium level and the initial surplus on the ruin probability. Keywords: discrete-time risk model; bonus-malus system; Markov modulated risk model; finite-time ruin; recursive computation; Lundberg inequality Citation: Osatakul, Dhiti, and Xueyuan Wu. 2021. Discrete-Time 1. Introduction Risk Models with Claim Correlated The commonly adopted bonus-malus system in the general insurance industry is Premiums in a Markovian based on a principal that insurance premiums can be adjusted based on the historical Environment. Risks 9: 26. claims record of individual policyholders. To be specific, the policyholders, who make no https://doi.org/10.3390/ claim or small claims in the latest policy year, will be offered a premium discount (also risks9010026 called ‘bonus’) on renewal. On the other hand, policyholders who make more claims than the given thresholds in the current policy year may need to pay higher premiums (also Received: 18 November 2020 called ‘malus’) if they decide to renew their policies. The bonus-malus system plays an Accepted: 10 January 2021 important role in the insurance industry, in particular in motor vehicle insurance sector, Published: 14 January 2021 because this system defines risk specific premium levels that help to sustain the total Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neu- premium pool in covering all motor insurance claims of the given insurance portfolio. The tral with regard to jurisdictional clai- discount in premium acts as an incentive to retain low-risk policyholders and to attract new ms in published maps and institutio- customers; on the other hand, the malus component prevents high-risk policyholders from nal affiliations. taking advantage of the low-risk policyholders by receiving disproportionate insurance benefits. The purpose of the bonus-malus system is to create heterogeneity by low-risk policyholders and high-risk policyholders. In other words, it acts as a posteriori classifier that differentiates the policyholders according to their driving behaviours besides the a Copyright: © 2021 by the authors. Li- priori variables. In addition, in terms of commercial purpose, the bonus-malus system censee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. is widely adopted in pricing by motor vehicle insurance companies to enhance their This article is an open access article competitiveness in the insurance market. distributed under the terms and con- The bonus-malus system related problems have remained a popular research field for ditions of the Creative Commons At- decades. De Pril (1979) proposed a continuous-time model for the bonus-malus system, tribution (CC BY) license (https:// which considers the phenomenon called ‘bonus-hunger ’. Lemaire and Zi (1994) conducted creativecommons.org/licenses/by/ a comparative analysis of 30 bonus-malus systems of 22 countries, and Lemaire (1995) 4.0/). Risks 2021, 9, 26. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks9010026 https://www.mdpi.com/journal/risks Risks 2021, 9, 26 2 of 23 provided insurance companies models to design their own bonus-malus systems that meet their objectives. Pinquet et al. (2001) considered the age of claims in their proposed model for the bonus-malus system. Baione et al. (2002) proposed the optimal bonus-malus system, which maximised the ‘transparency’ between policyholders and insurers and ‘financial balance conditions’. Pitrebois et al. (2006) designed a bonus-malus system with different types of claims. Dionne and Ghali (2005) conducted an empirical evaluation of the 1992 bonus-malus system in Tunisia. More recently, Denuit et al. (2019) consid- ered multivariate credibility modelling for usage-based motor insurance pricing with behavioural data, Vilar-Zanon et al. (2020) discussed an average model approach to experi- ence based premium rates discounts using the Spanish agricultural insurance data, and Ágoston and Gyetvai (2020) studied a joint optimisation problem of transition rules and the premium scale in a bonus-malus system. A lot more research work can be found in the references therein. The bonus-malus system has also been studied by many researchers in the context of risk models with claim-dependent premiums. As for the continuous-time setting, Afonso et al. (2009) studied the finite-time ruin probabilities in a continuous- time risk model that allows the premiums to be adjusted according to historical surplus levels. Li et al. (2015) studied the ruin probabilities under a continuous-time risk model with premium rate adjusted to the historical number of claims. Specifically, they applied the Bayesian credibility theory to find the posteriori expected number of claims and then adjusted the premium rate according to the posteriori estimator of claim numbers. They studied the impact of the two risks classified by ‘defectiveness’, i.e., the ‘historical’ stream and the ‘unforeseeable’ stream, on ruin probabilities. Constantinescu et al. (2016) studied the ruin probability in a regenerative risk process. They assume that the inter-arrival times of the process depend on the inter-arrival time between the current and previous claim. In other words, the distribution of the next claim waiting time depends on the waiting time between the current claim and the previous one. This assumption allows the premium rate to be adjusted according to the change of the inter-arrival time distribution. However, only two levels of premium rates are evaluated in their model: the bonus (discount) state and the base state. Moreover, Kucer ˇ ovský and Najafabadi (2017) studied the continuous-time risk model for a long term bonus-malus system in a steady state. They obtained the ruin probability in terms of closed-form solutions of an integral equation by the method of complex analysis. In addition, Afonso et al. (2017) analysed the impact of the different well-known bonus-malus scales and transition rules on the finite-time ruin probability in a continuous-time risk model. The posteriori premiums in their model are modified according to the historical claim record of each individual policyholder. In the most recent literature, Afonso et al. (2020) studied ruin probabilities and capital requirement for open automobile portfolios with a bonus-malus system based on claim counts. Under the discrete-time setting, Dufresne (1988) proposed the recursive algorithm to compute the ruin probabilities by using the stationary distributions of the bonus-malus system. Wagner (2002) considered a two-state Markov chain risk model and derived recur- sive formulae for ruin probabilities. Trufin and Loisel (2013) studied the ruin probabilities with premiums adjusted to the claims by Bühlmann credibility theory. They derived the asymptotic formulae for the ultimate ruin probabilities and the Lundberg coefficients for the light-tailed claims. In addition, they also derived the asymptotic formulae for the ulti- mate ruin probabilities for heavy-tailed claims. Further, Wu et al. (2015) derived recursive formulae and explicit formulae for the ultimate ruin probabilities in the case that premiums are correlated to claim amounts by using the two-state Markov Chain model. First of all, this paper is an extension of the models of Wu et al. (2015). As for the models of Wu et al. (2015), there are some strong assumptions regarding claim amounts and premiums. For example, the claims were assumed to take only three integer values and the differences between claims amount and premiums must be multiples of the lowest premium level. In addition, there are only three premium levels in their models. Taking into account these limitations, this paper aims to relax the strict assumptions such that Risks 2021, 9, 26 3 of 23 the individual claims can take any non-negative integer values and the premiums vary according to claims record in a broader bonus-malus context. Recursive equations are derived to calculate the finite-time ruin probabilities in the discrete-time setting. A similar approach was adopted in (Cai and Dickson (2004), sct. 2). In addition to considering premium adjustments according to aggregate claim amounts, this paper also considers the option of adjusting premiums based on recorded claim numbers, whereas Wu et al. (2015) only focused on the former case. Secondly, this paper combines inhomogeneity in claims experience with the bonus- malus system by introducing an external Markovian environment, which could see more applications in the real world. This is inspired by the fact that the external environment can affect the implementation of the bonus-malus system and should be taken into account by the insurers. As being said in Niemiec (2017), the external environment can affect the claim frequency and the bonus-malus system should be evaluated according to this factor. The term ‘external environment’ in this context means the factor that the insurers are not able to control but have an impact on the performance of the bonus-malus system. It can include economic conditions, weather conditions, regulations, competitiveness of competitors and so on. The topics about a bonus-malus system within an external environment have been studied by various researchers in the literature. For example, Viswanathan and Lemaire (2005) used a diffusion theory to study the evolution of market shares and claim frequencies of a two-company market when one insurance company applies the aggressive bonus-malus system. Park et al. (2010) used principal components analysis and regression models to evaluate the toughness of the bonus-malus system in Asia and its correlation with economic and cultural variables. Lee and Kim (2016) studied the impact of the change in a regulation of the bonus-malus system in Korea on moral hazard in motor vehicle insurance. Vilar-Zanon et al. (2020) introduced the new experience rating system, which is more suitable to the agricultural insurance in Spain and some other EU countries when high losses occur due to extreme weather. As for the studies of the risk of ruin within a Markovian environment, the most recent literature of Markov-modulated risk models includes Nie et al. (2020) and Li and Li (2020). In the former paper, the authors studied a discrete Markov-modulated risk model with delayed claims, random premium income, and a constant dividend barrier; whilst in the latter one, the authors studied some state-specific one-sided exit probabilities as well as the corresponding two-sided first exit probabilities in a Markov-modulated risk process. In this paper, we only focus on external environments that affect the implementation of the bonus-malus system in terms of varying the aggregate claims distribution such as economic environment and weather conditions. Regarding our proposed premium adjustment rules, we assume that the external environment is governed by an external Markov process. When the policies are renewed, the insurers will apply certain premium correction rules that correspond to the current external environment condition to determine the renewal premiums. As for a real-world application, it is not an issue in practice due to the short-term nature of most non-life insurance contracts. It means that the insurers are able to frequently modify the premium adjustment rules when the external environment changes. By applying this principle, it helps the insurers to better address the systematic risk when implementing the bonus-malus system in pricing. However, it can be tricky when insurers explain the environment-dependent premium changing rules to their policyholders since the rules are likely to change over time. The main goal of this paper is to numerically evaluate the impact of bonus-malus system on the ruin probabilities of the proposed risk models within an external Markovian environment. We aim to explore the following questions that may arise when imple- menting the bonus-malus system in practice through some numerical studies based on hypothetical assumptions: - What should the initial premium level be for new policyholders? - Which premium adjustment criterion is better in the proposed risk models: premiums adjusted by aggregate claims amount or premiums adjusted by claim frequency only? Risks 2021, 9, 26 4 of 23 - What is the likely impact of the initial external environment condition on the risk of ruin when the proposed premium adjustment rules are implemented? The main findings of our numerical studies are: - The choice of initial premium level for new policyholders is not an easy task. A low initial premium level tends to be very risky when the company’s initial capital amount is small. However, when the initial capital amount is sufficiently large, the insurer has more flexibility to lower the initial premium level that can attract more new policyholders and help with boosting the insurance business without significantly increasing the risk of insolvency. - The initial external environment condition does have a significant impact on the risk of ruin under the proposed premium adjustment rules, but the impact could be different from our first guess. - Adjusting premiums according to claim frequency can be riskier than the case of adjusting premiums by aggregate claims. This paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the models and assumptions of our study. Section 3 presents the finite-time ruin probabilities in a Markovian environment. Section 4 presents Lundberg inequalities for ruin probabilities. Section 5 presents the joint distribution of time of ruin, deficit, premium level and environment state at ruin. Section 6 provides some numerical studies with detailed comments. Concluding remarks and future research are given in Section 7. 2. Models and Assumptions + + Let c denote a premium level set where c = fc g , L = f1, 2, ..., lg, l 2 N , c 2 R . i i2L i Here c , i = 1, . . . , l, are premium levels per unit volume of risk. Let the external economic environmental status in time period [t 1, t), t 2 N be represented by a homogeneous and irreducible discrete-time Markov chainf J g with a finite state space R = f1, 2, ..., rg and t t2N a transition probability matrix P = [ p (g, h)] , where p (g, h) = P( J = hj J = g). J J g,h2R J t1 The stationary probability distribution of the Markov process is denoted by l = [l , ..., l ] 1 r where 0  l  1, i = 1, 2, . . . , r, and l = 1. Let fL g + be a stochastic process å t i i t2N i=1 monitoring the premium levels that the insurance company charges over time. Here L 2 c for any t 2 N and this premium level applies in the time period [t 1, t). Consider a general insurance surplus process of which the level of surplus at time k, k = 0, 1, . . . , is defined by U = U + (C S ) , for k 2 N , (1) 0 t t k å t=1 where S is the aggregate claims amount for time period [t 1, t) payable at time t, t 2 N ; U = u  0, u 2 N is the initial surplus level; C is the total premium for time period 0 t [t 1, t) received at time t 1 and C = L E[S ], t 2 N . Further, S has probability mass t t t t function (P.M.F.) P (s) and mean m , for J 2 R and s 2 N. S, J S, J t t The timing of all cash flows involved in the above insurance surplus process is illus- trated through the following timeline given in Figure 1 where year t denotes the period of [t 1, t), t 2 N . Risks 2021, 9, 26 5 of 23 S is paid at end of year t 1.  S is paid at the end of year t. t1 J is fixed for year t 1.  J is fixed for year t. t1 C is received at the beginning  C is received at the beginning t+1 of year t. of year t + 1. time 0 t 1 t Figure 1. The timeline of all cash flows. Given L = c and J = g, i 2 L, g 2 R, the first premium amount C can be 1 i 1 1 determined as follows C = c E[S ] = c m := a . (2) 1 i 1 i S,g i,g According to (2), theoretically a can be a non-integer value. However, an integer- i,g valued a is required for the computation of numerical results. There are two feasible i,g ways to convert non-integer a to an integer. Firstly, certain scaling-up can be applied i,g to make sure that a for all i 2 L and g 2 R are integer-valued. However, this method i,g may heavily increase the required computational time if the multiplier is a large number. Another way is to round each of a to its nearest integer, but this method potentially i,g reduces the level of accuracy in the computations. This negative impact might be minimal when considering large insurance portfolios. We remark that in this paper, we always assume that the parameters are integer-valued when necessary. In addition, all variables in our models are assumed to be integers to suit the derivations of the main recursive formulae in this paper. Non-integer valued parameters are not feasible in the recursive computational framework. The n-period finite-time ruin probability with initial surplus u, initial environment state g and initial premium level c is defined by, n 2 N , n n o y (u, n) = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g , (3) u 1 1 i,g k i k=1 where U is defined by (1) and the subscript u represents the condition U = u. By k 0 convention, for any i 2 L and g 2 R, 0 if u  0, n  0, y (u, n) = i,g 1 if u < 0, n  0. Further, we assume that the aggregate claim amounts S , t 2 N , are non-negative integer-valued random variables that follow a collective risk model structure: S = W , (4) å it i=1 where M is the total number of claims recorded in time period [t 1, t), t 2 N , with P.M.F. P (m) for J 2 R and m 2 N;fW g + , are individual claim sizes settled in time period M, J t it i2N [t 1, t). For the purpose of simplification, conditional on J , we assume that fW g + it i2N are independent and identically distributed (i.i.d.) with common P.M.F. P (w), w 2 N W, J and J 2 R. The claims number f M g and individual claim sizes fW g are assumed to be t t it independent of each other given J . t Risks 2021, 9, 26 6 of 23 For simplicity, we will use the symbol f to denote P (m) within the rest of this g,m M,g paper. One can show that, for s 2 N, P (s) = f P (s) S,g å g,m W,g m=0 m 0 with P (s) being the m-fold convolution of P (w) and P (0) = 1. W,g W,g W,g 2.1. Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims As introduced previously, this paper aims to consider a general bonus-malus premium system in a discrete-time setting. Let ft (s, g)g denote a general set of time- i j i,j2L;s2N;g2R homogeneous rules for premium variations, where t (s, g) = 1 if the aggregate claim i j S = s and environment state L = g lead to the transition from the premium level L = i to t t t L = j and t (s, g) = 0 otherwise. According to the definition, we have t (s, g) = 1 t+1 i j i j j=1 for any i 2 L, g 2 R, s 2 N. Let p (i, j) denote the probability that the premium level C,g,h moves from level i in initial environment state g to level j in environment state h, which can be expressed as, for any t 2 N , p (i, j) = PfL = j, J = h L = i, J = gg t t C,g,h t+1 t+1 = p (g, h) t (s, g)P (s), for i, j 2 L, g, h 2 R, (5) J å i j S,g s=0 where P (s), s 2 N, is the P.M.F. of aggregate claims in the environment state h with mean S,g m . The function t (s, g) is determined according to the given transition rule. From the S,h i j definition of p (i, j), considering a state space of f(i, g)g , its one-step transition i2L,g2R C,g,h probability matrix has the form P = [ p (i, j)] C C,g,h (lr)(lr) 2 3 p (1, 1)  p (1, l)  p (1, 1)  p (1, l) C,1,1 C,1,1 C,1,r C,1,r 6 7 . . . . . . 6 . . . . . . 7 . . . . . . 6 7 6 7 p (l, 1)  p (l, l)  p (l, 1)  p (l, l) 6 7 C,1,1 C,1,1 C,1,r C,1,r 6 7 . . . . 6 7 . . . . = . (6) 6 . . . . 7 6 7 6 p (1, 1)  p (1, l)  p (1, 1)  p (1, l)7 C,r,1 C,r,1 C,r,r C,r,r 6 7 . . . . 6 . . 7 . . . . . . 4 . . 5 . . . . p (l, 1)  p (l, l)  p (l, 1)  p (l, l) C,r,1 C,r,1 C,r,r C,r,r Note that the above matrix is constructed based on the combined statuses of pairs of premium level and environment state, which is a generalised version of the usual transition matrix for individual premium levels or transition matrix for individual environment states. The associated stationary probability distribution of P is denoted by p = [p ] , for C,g,h ig lr i 2 L and g 2 R. From (5) we have, for j 2 L, h 2 R, l r p = p p (i, j) jh å å ig C,g,h i=1 g=1 l r ¥ = p p (g, h) t (s, g)P (s). ig J i j s,g å å å i=1 g=1 s=0 Following a common practice, we would also assume that the surplus process (1) satisfies the positive safety loading conditions, for any i 2 L, g 2 R, a > m . ig S,g Risks 2021, 9, 26 7 of 23 Remark 1. The above positive safety loading condition assumption is more conservative than it usually appears in the Markov modulated risk model literature, because it needs to be in such form to enable the generalised Lundberg inequalities discussed in Section 4. 2.2. Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency When periodic premiums adjust according to the claim frequency experience rather than the aggregate claim amounts, the transition probability p in (5) needs to be C,g,h(i,j) modified as p (i, j) = p (g, h) t (m, g) f , for i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, (7) C,g,h J å i j g,m m=0 where f , for m 2 N, is the P.M.F. of the claims number in the environment state g. g,m 3. Finite-Time Ruin Probabilities In this section, we shall derive recursive formulae to compute the finite-time ruin prob- abilities that are defined by (3). We consider the two options of varying premiums separately. 3.1. Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims According to the assumptions in Section 2.1, the n-period finite-time ruin probability y (u, n), satisfies the following recursive formula. i,g Theorem 1. For u  0, n 2 N , i 2 L and g 2 R, u+a r l i,g y (u, n + 1) = p (g, h) t (s, g)y (u + a s, n)P (s) i,g å J å å i j j,h i,g S,g h=1 j=1 s=0 + P (s) (8) S,g s=u+a +1 i,g with y (u, 1) = å P (s). i,g S,g s=u+a +1 i,g Proof of Theorem 1. From (3), we have n+1 n o y (u, n + 1) = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g i,g k 1 i 1 k=1 u+a i,g n n+1 o ¥ = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g, S = s P (s) + P (s) å k 1 i 1 1 S,g å S,g s=0 s=u+c m +1 k=1 i S,h u+a i,g n n+1 o = t (s, g)P (U < 0) L = c , J = g P (s) å å i j u+a s k 2 j 1 S,g i,g j=1 s=0 k=2 + P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g u+a i,g n+1 r l n o = p (g, h) t (s, g)P (U < 0) L = c , J = h P (s) å J å å i j u+a s 2 j 2 S,g i,g k j=1 s=0 h=1 k=2 + P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g u+a r l i,g ¥ = p (g, h) t (s, g)y (u + a s, n)P (s) + P (s). å J å å i j j,h i,g S,g å S,g s=0 h=1 j=1 s=u+a +1 i,g Risks 2021, 9, 26 8 of 23 Since y (u, 1) only measures the probability of ruin of the business within one time i,g period, the verification of the given boundary condition is trivial. 3.2. Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency For this section, we change the transition rule for premium adjustment from consider- ing the aggregate claims to number of claims. According to the assumptions in Section 2.2, the n-period-finite-time ruin probability with premiums adjusted according to claims num- bers, initial premium level i and initial environment state g satisfies the following the recursive formulae. Theorem 2. For u  0, n 2 N , i 2 L and g 2 R, u+a u+a i,g i,g r l y (u, n + 1) = p (g, h) f t (m, g) P (s)y (u + a s, n) i,g å J å å g,m i j å j,h i,g W,g s=m h=1 j=1 m=0 + P (s) (9) S,g s=u+a +1 i,g with y (u, 1) = P (s). i,g å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g Proof of Theorem 2. Since the proof of Theorem 2 is largely similar to the proof of Theorem 1, we omit the details here. Its full proof can be found in Appendix A. 4. Lundberg Inequalities for Ruin Probabilities In previous sections, we studied the finite-time ruin probabilities, which reflect the risk of ruin for insurers within finite terms. However, in practice, insurers and insurance regulators also concern about the risk of ruin in the long term, where ultimate ruin proba- bilities are the appropriate measurement instead of the finite-time ones. The ultimate ruin probabilities can be defined by letting n = ¥ in (3), which is denoted by y (u), i 2 L and i,g g 2 R. Due to the general settings of premium changing rules and aggregate claim distri- butions, neither explicit results nor recursive formulae for the ultimate ruin probabilities can be obtained easily. How to extend our finite-time ruin probability recursive formulae to the infinite-time context remains an open problem for the future. Instead of calculating the ultimate ruin probabilities directly, we would derive some upper bounds for them in this section. It is inspired by the Lundberg inequality result in the classical risk model. Some Lundberg-type upper bounds, named as generalised Lundberg inequalities, are obtained with the induction method in both cases of premium variations. A similar approach was used in Cai and Dickson (2004). To calculate the generalised Lundberg inequalities, the stationary distribution p defined in Section 2.1 is needed, which represents the long-term probabilities of premium levels and environment states. We consider the case of premiums adjusted by aggregate claims first. Following the classical risk model Lundberg inequality approach, to derive an upper bound for the ultimate-time ruin probabilities, we need to find the corresponding adjustment coefficient for our generalised risk model first. Let g > 0, i 2 L, g 2 R, be constants satisfying the i,g following equation, g a g S i,g i,g i,g 1 e E e J = g = 1. (10) Then g = inf fg g is a generalised adjustment coefficient. It can be shown that, i,g i2L; g2R by the log-convexity property of the moment generating functions, for any i 2 L, g 2 R, g a g S i,g 1 e E e J = g  1. (11) We can obtain the following main result: Risks 2021, 9, 26 9 of 23 Theorem 3. Let g > 0 be the generalised adjustment coefficient defined above, then for any i 2 L, g 2 R, gu y (u)  be , (12) i,g g t ¥ e å P (s) s=t+1 S,g where b = sup . g s e P (s) S,g t0; g2R s=t+1 Proof of Theorem 3. Firstly, we need to prove by induction that for any n > 0, y (u, n) i,g gu be . When n = 1, we have, for i 2 L, g 2 R, y (u, 1) = P (s) i,g å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g g(u+a ) ¥ i,g ¥ h i e P (t) S,g t=u+a +1 i,g g(u+a ) g s i,g = e e P (s) å S,g g t e P (t) S,g t=u+a +1 s=u+a +1 i,g i,g g(u+a ) g s i,g be e P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g g a g u g S i,g 1 be e E e J = g gu be . (13) Assume the result holds true for the case of n  1, i.e., gu y (u, n)  be , i 2 L, g 2 R. i,g We only need to show that it also holds for the case of n + 1. From (8) and (13), we have u+a i,g r l y (u, n + 1) = p (g, h) t (s, g)y (u + a s, n)P (s) i,g å J å å i j j,h i,g S,g h=1 j=1 s=0 + P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g u+a i,g r l g(u+a s) i,g b e p (g, h) t (s, g)P (s) J i j S,g å å å s=0 h=1 j=1 g(u+a s) i,g +b e P (s) å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g g(u+a s) i,g = b e P (s) å S,g s=0 g u g a g S i,g = be e E e J = g gu be . By induction, we conclude that for any n > 0, gu y (u, n)  be . i,g Since y (u) = lim y (u, n), this upper bound also holds for y (u). i,g i,g i,g n!¥ Risks 2021, 9, 26 10 of 23 Remark 2. From the similarity between the recursive formulae given in Theorems 1 and 2, one can see that the Lundberg inequality (12) also applies to the ultimate ruin probabilities in the case of premiums adjusted by claims frequency. 5. The Joint Distribution of Premium Level and Environment State at Ruin In this section, given that ruin occurs, the joint distribution of the premium level and environment state at ruin is studied. 5.1. Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims Let T = min k : U < 0 U = u be the time of ruin with initial surplus u. Define u 0 c (u, n, j, h) = P T  n, L = c , J = h L = c , J = g u u T T i,g j 1 i 1 u u to be the probability that ruin occurs within the first n time periods with the premium level c and the environment state h at ruin given the initial surplus u, initial premium level i and initial environment state g, where u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R. Then, the joint probability of premium level c and environment state h at ruin given that ruin occurs within the next n periods with initial surplus u, initial premium level c and initial environment state g, denoted by c (u, n, j, h), takes the form i,g c (u, n, j, h) i,g c (u, n, j, h) = , i,g y (u, n) i,g where y (u, n) can be computed using (8). i,g A trivial relationship between c (u, n, j, h) and y (u, n) is that, for u  0, n 2 N , i,g i,g i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, l r c (u, n, j, h) = y (u, n). å å i,g i,g j=1 h=1 Parallel to Theorem 1, we can show that c (u, n, j, h) satisfies the following i,g recursive formula. Theorem 4. For u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, u+c r l c (u, n + 1, j, h) = p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h) i,g å J å S,g å i j j ,h i 0 0 s=0 h =1 j =1 + 1 1 P (s), (14) å S,g fi=jg fg=hg s=u+c +1 where c (u, 1, j, h) = 1 1 P (s). i,g S,g fi=jg fg=hg s=u+c +1 i Risks 2021, 9, 26 11 of 23 Proof of Theorem 4. Following the definition of c (u, n, j, h), we have, for u  0, n 2 N , i,g i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, c (u, n + 1, j, h) i,g n o = P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = g u u T j T 1 i 1 u u h u+c i r ¥ = p (g, h ) P (s) + P (s) J S,g S,g å å å s=0 s=u+c +1 h =1 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = h , S = s u u T j T 1 i 2 1 u u u+c ¥ r l = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g) fi=jg fg=hg å S,g å J å S,g å i j 0 0 s=u+c +1 h =1 s=0 j =1 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h , S = s u u T j T 2 j 2 1 u u u+c ¥ r l = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g) å S,g å J å S,g å i j fi=jg fg=hg 0 0 s=u+c +1 h =1 s=0 j =1 n o P T  n, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h u+c s u+c s T j T 2 j 2 i i u+c s u+c s i i r u+c l = p (g, h ) P (s) t 0(s, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h) å J å S,g å i j j ,h i 0 0 h =1 s=0 j =1 + 1 1 P (s). fi=jg fg=hg å S,g s=u+c +1 The verification of the boundary condition is trivial. 5.2. Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency The notations and definitions are same as the case of premiums adjusted according to c (u,n,j,h) i,g aggregate claims. The corresponding c (u, n, j, h) is also computed by , where i,g y (u,n) i,g y (u, n) is calculated by (9) and c (u, n, j, h) satisfied the following recursive formulae. i,g i,g Theorem 5. For u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, ¥ r u+c u+c i i 0 m c (u, n + 1, j, h) = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) g,m i,g fi=jg fg=hg å S,g å J å å W,g m=0 s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 t 0(m, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h), (15) å i j j ,h i j =1 where c (u, 1, j, h) = 1 1 P (s). i,g S,g fi=jg fg=hg s=u+c +1 Proof of Theorem 5. Since the proof of Theorem 5 is largely similar to the proof of Theorem 4, we omit the details here. Its full proof can be found in Appendix B. 6. Some Numerical Results In this section we shall provide two numerical examples that represent the two varying premium cases discussed previously in this paper and the numerical results regarding the ruin probabilities are given with some concluding remarks. Risks 2021, 9, 26 12 of 23 6.1. An Example for Premiums Adjusted by Aggregate Claims This example is designed for the case that premiums are adjusted according to aggre- gate claims. We assume that the economic state is fixed over a year from the beginning, and the economic state affects the aggregate claims distribution in the year. It implies that the yearly aggregate claims distribution changes whenever the economic state changes. The aggregate claims are assumed to be negative binomial distributed as follows: • Economic state 1 (normal): mean = 10, variance = 101.743; • Economic state 2 (deflation): mean = 5, variance = 54.664; • Economic state 3 (inflation): mean = 15, variance = 268.187. The one-step transition probability matrix of the economic state is 2 3 0.8 0.1 0.1 4 5 P = p (g, h) = 0.3 0.65 0.05 , J J g,h=1,2,3 0.3 0.05 0.65 with stationary distribution l = [l = 0.6, l = 0.2, l = 0.2]. The expected long-term 1 2 3 aggregate claim amount is: (0.6 10) + (0.2 5) + (0.2 15) = 10. Suppose the set of premium loading is c = f120%, 140%, 160%, 180%, 200%g. The rules for adjusting the premiums are given as follows. 1. If the recorded aggregate claims in the current period is no more than the 30th per- centile of the aggregate claim distribution, then the premium level for the next period will move to the lower premium level or stay in the lowest one; 2. If the recorded aggregate claims in the current period is more than the 30th percentile but no more than the 70th percentile of the aggregate claim distribution, then the premium level for the next period will remain in the current premium level; 3. If the recorded aggregate claims in the current period is more than the 70th percentile of the aggregate claim distribution, then the premium level for the next period will move to the higher premium level or stay in the highest one. Remark 3. • The transition matrix of economic state given above is a hypothetical one. Different matrices will generate different sequences of premiums in the future. How to obtain a reliable estimate of such a transition matrix in real-life is beyond the scope of this study. Econometric studies could possibly provide answers to this question. • The above set of premium rules is again a hypothetical one and is a much simplified version of the real-life bonus-malus rules. This helps to simplify the computational process and can sufficiently showcase our key results obtained in the main text before. • The premium loadings given in c do not indicate the bonus or malus cases directly. Only when the initial premium level (or base level) is chosen, then we can tell whether a given premium level is a bonus (lower than base level) or a malus case (higher than base level). According to the above transition rule, we can calculate the transition matrix among premium levels, i.e., P = [ p (i, j)] , defined in (6) in Appendix C. Using C,g,h (lr)(lr) P , we can find the long-term stationary joint distribution of the premium levels and economics conditions: 2 3 0.1270, 0.1234, 0.1199, 0.1165, 0.1132 4 5 p = [p ] = 0.0421, 0.0411, 0.0400, 0.0389, 0.0379 . ig i2L,g2R 0.0424, 0.0411, 0.0400, 0.0388, 0.0377 The expected long-term premium income calculated from p is 15.89 per time unit, which is roughly 60% greater than the expected long-term aggregate claim amount per time unit. Assuming the initial economic state is 1 (normal condition), using (8) we calculate Risks 2021, 9, 26 13 of 23 the finite-time ruin probabilities y (u, 40), i = 1, . . . , 5, and the associated Lundberg upper i1 bounds for the ultimate ruin probabilities y (u) can be found using (12). These results are ig summarised in Table 1 and Figure 2 below. As shown in Table 1 and Figure 2, one can see that y (u, 40), i = 1, . . . , 5 are ordered i1 by their initial premium levels, the lower the initial premium level is, the higher the finite-time ruin probabilities. Secondly, the initial surplus level u has a significant impact on differentiating the five finite-time ruin probabilities: these probabilities differ more from each other when u is small, but this impact tends to wear off when u becomes larger. For example, for u = 0, y (0, 40) = 0.581516, whereas y (0, 40) = 0.220787 1,1 5,1 (around 0.36 in difference). On the other hand, for u = 50, y (50, 40) = 0.039369 and 1,1 y (50, 40) = 0.007212 (only 0.03 in difference). Its implications coincide with the practical 5,1 concerns when choosing the initial premium level with different u levels: a low initial premium level tends to be very risky when u is small. However, when the initial surplus u is sufficiently large, the insurer has more flexibility to lower the initial premium level that can attract more new policyholders and help with boosting the insurance business without significantly increasing the risk of insolvency. One obvious observation in Figure 2 regarding the upper bound is that it is very loose for all five versions of finite-time ruin probabilities. An argument for this is that the generalised adjustment coefficient g adopted in (12) is quite conservative, since it is determined by the scenario that has the highest ruin probabilities by its definition. Also, the upper bound given in (12) is for the ultimate time ruin probabilities, so tend to be fairly loose for finite-time ruin probabilities with n = 40. In practice, the insurer can use these upper bounds to evaluate the worst-scenario risk of ruin in the long run. Table 1. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,1 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,1 2,1 3,1 4,1 5,1 0 0.581516 0.485600 0.370290 0.278787 0.220787 0.982500 10 0.346148 0.268051 0.189482 0.135426 0.106381 0.823486 20 0.202262 0.147489 0.097952 0.067067 0.052281 0.690207 30 0.117224 0.081516 0.051458 0.034011 0.026317 0.578500 40 0.067836 0.045466 0.027558 0.017698 0.013597 0.484872 50 0.039369 0.025658 0.015062 0.009450 0.007212 0.406397 70 0.013508 0.008491 0.004769 0.002893 0.002181 0.285494 90 0.004775 0.002943 0.001609 0.000954 0.000713 0.200560 120 0.001052 0.000638 0.000340 0.000197 0.000146 0.118091 150 0.000240 0.000144 0.000075 0.000043 0.000031 0.069532 200 0.000021 0.000012 0.000006 0.000004 0.000003 0.028761 First of all, given each initial economic state, we make similar observations in the trending in finite-time ruin probabilities when u and i change. Following that, comparing the three cases with different initial economic states, we have some interesting findings. Firstly, when u = 0 and three i cases of u = 10, the deflation economic state (state 2) leads to the highest finite-time ruin probabilities whilst the inflation economic state (state 3) has the lowest finite-time ruin probabilities. Secondly, when the initial premium level is at the lowest one (i = 1) and u  10, the inflation economic state leads to the highest ruin probabilities whilst the deflation state has the lowest ones. For remaining cases, the inflation state usually ranks the highest in finite-time ruin probabilities and the normal economic state ranks the lowest. We struggle to find intuitive reasons behind these observations. One contributing factor is the initial premium amount. The ranking of ruin probabilities when u = 0 coincides with the ranking of the initial premium amounts correspond to the three initial economic states, which again confirms the significant role of the early premium income in keeping solvency when there is no capital buffer in the first place. Based on these observations, it is fair to say that both initial economic state and initial premium level play important roles in determining the finite-time ruin probabilities of the insurance business. Therefore, the insurers must keep a close eye on this matter when optimising Risks 2021, 9, 26 14 of 23 their premium-changing strategies. Next, we shall dig further into the relationship between u, the premium level and economic state at ruin given ruin occurs. As an example, we calculate the joint distribution of the premium level and economic state at ruin given the ruin occurs within 10 periods, i.e., c (0, 10, j, h), making use of the result (14). i,g y (u, 40) 1,1 0.9 y (u, 40) 2,1 0.8 y (u, 40) 3,1 0.7 y (u, 40) 4,1 y (u, 40) 0.6 5,1 UB 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 40 80 120 160 200 Figure 2. y (u, 40) with the upper bounds. i,1 For the initial economics state 2 (deflation condition) and state 3 (inflation condition), the finite-time ruin probability results are given in Tables 2 and 3, respectively. Table 2. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,2 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,2 2,2 3,2 4,2 5,2 0 0.602651 0.530232 0.432010 0.346695 0.290467 0.982500 10 0.340618 0.280003 0.210953 0.159843 0.132489 0.823486 20 0.194130 0.151662 0.107550 0.077895 0.063776 0.690207 30 0.110690 0.083187 0.056257 0.039292 0.031786 0.578500 40 0.063296 0.046186 0.030090 0.020401 0.016316 0.484872 50 0.036402 0.025979 0.016437 0.010875 0.008605 0.406397 70 0.012333 0.008554 0.005196 0.003313 0.002573 0.285494 90 0.004325 0.002954 0.001750 0.001087 0.000832 0.200560 120 0.000946 0.000638 0.000369 0.000223 0.000168 0.118091 150 0.000215 0.000143 0.000082 0.000049 0.000036 0.069532 200 0.000019 0.000012 0.000007 0.000004 0.000003 0.028761 In Table 4, c (0, 10, 1, 1) is the highest one among all 15 cases, much larger than 1,1 all the other cases. It means that, given that u = 0 and ruin occurs by time 10, the most likely premium level and economic state combination at ruin is the same as the initial combination (i = 1, g = 1). The second and third most likely cases are (j = 2, h = 1) and (j = 1, h = 3) that are adjacent combinations of (i = 1, g = 1). This implies that without any capital buffer at the beginning and charging the lowest level of premium, if ruin occurs early, then it will occur within the first few time units before making many transitions in either premium levels or economic states. Of course, the initial premium level and initial economic state as well as u all play an important roles in this. We shall continue this investigation in our next scenario. Risks 2021, 9, 26 15 of 23 Table 3. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,3 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,3 2,3 3,3 4,3 5,3 0 0.536216 0.441881 0.338071 0.259681 0.209647 0.982500 10 0.362565 0.284586 0.209476 0.157582 0.127362 0.823486 20 0.240562 0.181306 0.129259 0.095593 0.077312 0.690207 30 0.157427 0.114621 0.079529 0.057972 0.046900 0.578500 40 0.101979 0.072065 0.048833 0.035150 0.028439 0.484872 50 0.065557 0.045126 0.029942 0.021312 0.017240 0.406397 70 0.026650 0.017546 0.011225 0.007835 0.006334 0.285494 90 0.010669 0.006769 0.004198 0.002881 0.002327 0.200560 120 0.002651 0.001606 0.000957 0.000643 0.000519 0.118091 150 0.000647 0.000377 0.000217 0.000144 0.000116 0.069532 200 0.000060 0.000033 0.000018 0.000012 0.000009 0.028761 Scenario 1. Let u = 0, i = 1 and g = 1. Values of c (0, 10, j, h) are summarised in Table 4. 1,1 Table 4. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.758260 0.066721 0.017378 0.004019 0.000892 h = 2 0.031033 0.015421 0.005128 0.001372 0.000344 h = 3 0.062983 0.026394 0.007770 0.001865 0.000421 Scenario 2. Keep u and g unchanged, but let i = 5, the highest level of premium. The correspond- ing results are given in Table 5. Table 5. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 5,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.000113 0.000726 0.004665 0.047550 0.800367 h = 2 0.000037 0.000231 0.001394 0.008976 0.038254 h = 3 0.000408 0.001594 0.005976 0.024634 0.065076 In Table 5, c (0, 10, 5, 1) is the highest one among all 15 cases, much larger than all 5,1 the others. Again, given that u = 0 and ruin occurs by time 10, the most likely premium level and economic state combination at ruin is the same as the initial combination. The second and third most likely cases are (j = 5, h = 3) and (j = 4, h = 1), the adjacent combinations of (i = 5, g = 1). It looks like when u = 0, even charging the given highest level of premium, if we know ruin occurs early, then it will still occur within the first few time units. This is a similar observation to Scenario 1. This implies that, under our model assumptions, the initial surplus plays a more important role in the insolvency risk than the initial premium level. For the purpose of comparison, we shall consider one more scenario of u = 100 to see any different observations from the u = 0 scenarios. Scenario 3. Let u = 100, i = 1 and g = 1. The corresponding results are given in Table 6. Table 6. Results for c (100, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.016169 0.053910 0.071874 0.054714 0.043763 h = 2 0.002011 0.008437 0.013755 0.012849 0.012611 h = 3 0.098078 0.218514 0.204083 0.118145 0.071086 Risks 2021, 9, 26 16 of 23 In contrast to the previous two scenarios, in Table 6, the top four most likely com- binations of premium level and economic state at ruin are (j = 2, h = 3), (j = 3, h = 3), (j = 4, h = 3), and (j = 1, h = 3). It implies that when the initial surplus is large, given ruin occurs, then ruin would most likely occur under the worst economic state, i.e., h = 3, which by assumption has the highest expected aggregate claim amount per time unit. Again, the premium level at ruin seems relatively less influential than the economic state regarding insolvency. Moreover, the values of c (100, 10, j, h) in Table 6 are more evenly spread out 1,1 than the results in Tables 4 and 5. This is because with u = 100, there are more chances that the insurance business could stay solvent in the first few periods and ruin would occur later. The longer the surplus process runs, then the less predictable it is, thus the premium level and economic state combination at ruin. 6.2. An Example for Premiums Adjusted by Claim Frequency In this example, we shall consider automobile insurance business and we replace the external economic environment by weather conditions. We assume that the premium levels are adjusted according to the claim frequency and the weather condition has a significant impact on the claim frequency of automobile insurance policyholders. • The claim frequency is modelled by Poisson distribution with mean 1.57, 0.785 and 2.355 for weather state 1 (normal condition), 2 (less severe condition) and 3 (severe weather condition) respectively. • The one-step transition probability matrix of weather states (environment state) with the corresponding stationary probability distribution are the same as the ones for the external economic states in the previous example. Similar to the previous example, the weather state is assumed to be fixed over a year from the beginning and the premiums depend on the current weather state. • The individual claim size distribution under each weather state is assumed to be 1.57 1.57 (w1) 10 geometric with P.M.F. P (w) = ( )(1 ) for w  1 and mean . Then 10 10 1.57 the expected aggregate claim amount under weather state 1, 2, and 3 is 10, 5 and 15, respectively. The expected long-term aggregate claim amount is 10, which is the same as the one in the previous example as well. We continue to use the same set of premium loading as the one in the previous example, i.e., c = f120%, 140%, 160%, 180%, 200%g. The rules for adjusting premiums are given as follows: 1. If the number of claims in the current period is 0, then the premium level for the next period will move to the lower premium level or stay in the lowest one; 2. If the number of claims in the current period is greater than 0 but no more than 2, then the premium level for the next period will remain in the current premium level; 3. If the number of claims in the current period is more 2, then the premium level for the next period will move to the higher premium level or stay in the highest one. According to the above transition rules for premium adjustments, we can also find its associated transition matrix among the premium levels in the Appendix D, and the following long-term stationary joint distribution of the premium levels and weather states: 2 3 0.1429, 0.1214, 0.1119, 0.1089, 0.1150 4 5 p = [p ] = 0.0702, 0.0394, 0.0350, 0.0314, 0.0241 . ig i2L,g2R 0.0328, 0.0374, 0.0373, 0.0380, 0.0545 Using p, one can see that the expected long-term premium is around 15.9 per time unit, which is about 60% greater than the expected long-term aggregate claims per time unit. Remarkably, the expected long-term premium loading in this example is comparable to the one in the previous example. We make the expected long-term premium income and expected long-term aggregate claims of these two examples comparable on purpose such that a comparison is feasible between the two different types of premium transition Risks 2021, 9, 26 17 of 23 rules regarding their impact on the ruin probabilities. Similarly, in the following we use the result (9) to calculate y (u, 40) and use (12) to calculate the upper bounds for the ultimate i,1 time ruin probabilities y (u). The results are summarised in Table 7 and Figure 3 below. i,1 Table 7. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,1 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,1 2,1 3,1 4,1 5,1 0 0.605971 0.509785 0.394719 0.299570 0.235311 0.971992 10 0.388786 0.299805 0.209603 0.146053 0.110407 0.731630 20 0.236054 0.167432 0.106238 0.068367 0.050195 0.550706 30 0.137875 0.090424 0.052377 0.031307 0.022445 0.414523 40 0.078166 0.047692 0.025389 0.014180 0.009959 0.312016 50 0.043249 0.024708 0.012176 0.006393 0.004407 0.234858 70 0.012487 0.006372 0.002750 0.001299 0.000865 0.133065 90 0.003391 0.001581 0.000614 0.000266 0.000172 0.075391 120 0.000441 0.000186 0.000064 0.000025 0.000015 0.032152 150 0.000053 0.000021 0.000007 0.000002 0.000001 0.013712 200 0.000001 0.000001 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.003313 y (u, 40) 1,1 0.9 y (u, 40) 2,1 0.8 y (u, 40) 3,1 0.7 y (u, 40) 4,1 0.6 y (u, 40) 5,1 UB 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 40 80 120 160 200 Figure 3. y (u, 40) with the upper bounds. i,1 Firstly, our main findings in Table 7 and Figure 3 are consistent with those in Table 1 and Figure 2 in terms of the impact of the initial premium level and initial surplus level on ruin probabilities. Secondly, given the same initial external environment state, when u is small the premium adjustment rules based on claim frequency have a negative impact on the finite-time ruin probabilities comparing with the rules by aggregate claim amounts. Also, this effect becomes more significant when the initial premium level is lower. For instance when i = 1 this effect applies to u  50 but it only takes effect for u  20 when i = 5. This is reasonable since the transition rules that adjust the premiums according to the claim frequency can not fully reflect the historical claims experience, which causes higher risk of ruin when u is small. On the contrary, when u is large enough, the premium rules by claim frequency seems to lower the insolvency risk of the insurer comparing with the other type of rules. This implies that, in practice, the insurers should carefully design their bonus-malus rules by taking into account factors like the capital adequacy level since the proposed rules could have significant impact on insolvency risk. Next, we shall investigate the finite-time ruin probabilities with initial weather state 2 and 3, which are shown in Tables 8 and 9. Risks 2021, 9, 26 18 of 23 Table 8. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,2 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,2 2,2 3,2 4,2 5,2 0 0.647608 0.600217 0.511647 0.414121 0.332302 0.971992 10 0.410970 0.362287 0.281517 0.204813 0.150624 0.731630 20 0.251122 0.211238 0.150889 0.099501 0.067739 0.550706 30 0.148774 0.119900 0.079446 0.047947 0.030482 0.414523 40 0.085828 0.066553 0.041270 0.023024 0.013769 0.312016 50 0.048375 0.036238 0.021204 0.011040 0.006249 0.234858 70 0.014483 0.010237 0.005448 0.002533 0.001305 0.133065 90 0.004064 0.002744 0.001359 0.000580 0.000276 0.075391 120 0.000550 0.000353 0.000162 0.000063 0.000027 0.032152 150 0.000069 0.000042 0.000018 0.000007 0.000003 0.013712 200 0.000002 0.000001 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.003313 Table 9. y (u, 40) values with upper bounds (UB). i,3 u y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) y (u, 40) UB 1,3 2,3 3,3 4,3 5,3 0 0.555437 0.430304 0.315517 0.231635 0.179284 0.971992 10 0.354335 0.249205 0.167191 0.115193 0.087273 0.731630 20 0.212928 0.136511 0.084156 0.054739 0.040872 0.550706 30 0.122699 0.072029 0.040953 0.025268 0.018672 0.414523 40 0.068509 0.037011 0.019486 0.011455 0.008399 0.312016 50 0.037306 0.018650 0.009134 0.005138 0.003744 0.234858 70 0.010434 0.004543 0.001955 0.001019 0.000736 0.133065 90 0.002749 0.001066 0.000411 0.000202 0.000144 0.075391 120 0.000343 0.000116 0.000039 0.000018 0.000013 0.032152 150 0.000040 0.000012 0.000004 0.000002 0.000001 0.013712 200 0.000001 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.003313 According to the results in Tables 8 and 9, the trending of finite-time ruin probabilities when u and i change is still consistent with Table 7. In contrast to the previous premium- changing category (by aggregate claims), when the premiums change according to claim frequency experience, there is an overall consistent ranking in the finite-time ruin probabil- ities among the three initial weather conditions, i.e., less severe initial weather condition (state 2) leads to the highest ruin probabilities whilst the severe initial weather condition (state 3) has the lowest ruin probabilities. This ranking can be explained by the level of right-skewness of the Compound Poisson distributions corresponding to the aggregate claims under each weather condition. Apparently, state 2 has the highest right-skewness whilst state 3 has the lowest, which relates to the risk of insolvency. At last, we shall use the (15) to compute the joint distribution of the premium level and weather condition at ruin given ruin occurs within 10 time periods. The results are given in Tables 10–12, where the scenarios considered are the same as Scenario 1–3 in the previous example. Table 10. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.788065 0.069503 0.012257 0.002256 0.000437 h = 2 0.041473 0.010975 0.002007 0.000384 0.000077 h = 3 0.045738 0.020304 0.005216 0.001088 0.000220 Risks 2021, 9, 26 19 of 23 Table 11. Results for c (0, 10, j, h). 5,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.000410 0.001394 0.005025 0.039455 0.863448 h = 2 0.000204 0.000681 0.002484 0.010320 0.034591 h = 3 0.000116 0.000389 0.001216 0.006851 0.033414 Table 12. Results for c (100, 10, j, h). 1,1 j = 1 2 3 4 5 h = 1 0.066714 0.193377 0.205458 0.115465 0.057055 h = 2 0.017125 0.033472 0.034556 0.020260 0.010142 h = 3 0.020572 0.071252 0.082757 0.047871 0.023924 From Tables 10 and 11, one can see that under Scenario 1 and Scenario 2 (both with u = 0) we get similar main findings to those in the previous example. It is worth noting that in Scenario 3 where u = 100, we get opposite findings comparing with our previous example. The top four most likely combinations of premium level and weather conditions at ruin are (j = 3, h = 1), (j = 2, h = 1), (j = 4, h = 1) and (j = 3, h = 3), mostly associated with the normal weather conditions under which the claim experience should be the middle one. This is totally different from the previous example where in Scenario 3 the most likely combinations come from the worst economic state under which the claim experience is the worst. The most likely explanation lies in the way premiums are being adjusted as well as the claim experience assumptions under different weather conditions. To be more specific, we assume that individual claim amounts are not affected by weather conditions, but claim frequency does. Under the normal weather condition (i = 1), the current premium level is likely to stay unchanged. However, under severe weather condition (i = 3), average claim frequency is high, which leads to moving the next premium level up. To a certain extent, the worsened claim experience is off-set by the increased premium amount, which leads to a lower overall insolvency risk than the normal weather condition. We remark that this observation might not hold when the parameter assumptions are changed, which result in a different trade-off between the claim experience and premium adjustment. Last but not least, we make a further comparison between the above two numerical examples, as the risk models constructed in those two examples are in general comparable, for example, equal average aggregate claim amounts as well as the same premium levels. We can see that the case of adjusting premiums according to claim frequency is riskier than the case of adjusting premiums according to aggregate claims under our assumptions. This finding also has some material implication for the insurance companies on how to choose an appropriate premium adjustment strategy. 7. Conclusions and Discussions In this paper we considered a discrete-time risk model, which allows the premium to be adjusted according to claims experience. The premium correction was based on the well-known bonus-malus system and the claims experience was assumed to depend on an external Markovian environment (economic and/or natural environment). As a result, the evaluation of this unusual bonus-malus framework, which has non-homogeneous premium transition rules, became the main objective of this paper. To have a better coverage, two types of premium changing criteria were examined throughout the paper: aggregate claims criterion vs. claim frequency criterion. The basis of our evaluation is the risk of ruin for the proposed risk model with the given set of initial parameters, i.e., initial surplus, initial premium level and initial environment state. On the one hand, recursive formulae were obtained to calculate the finite-time ruin probabilities and Lundberg-type upper bounds were derived to evaluate the ultimate ruin probabilities in both cases. On the other hand, the joint distribution of premium level and environment state at ruin was also studied. Risks 2021, 9, 26 20 of 23 Through our numerical studies, we find that both the initial premium level and the initial environment state have a significant impact on the insolvency risk. We observed that there is no straightforward ordering on the insolvency risk among cases with different initial environmental state, which can be seen as the consequence of a combined effect of non-homogeneous loss distributions, premium rule assumptions as well as the initial surplus level. This shed a light on the importance of determining the proper base premium level in a given external environment when insurers implement the bonus-malus system in premium corrections. This paper focused on the ruin probabilities when evaluating the proposed bonus- malus system within a Markovian environment. However, how to implement the premium corrections in real life based on the main findings in this paper remains a very challenging task, as there will be no fixed premium changing rules when the external environment changes. A possible solution is that the insurer designs a special scoring system and uses it to evaluate its policyholders’ claim experience. For instance, at the end of each policy year a policyholder receives a certain score based on the ordering of his/her claim experience in the whole insurance portfolio, and then a bonus or malus can be offered in the renewal premium based on the scores. This type of score-based premium rules can effectively address the impact of external environment on premium corrections. This non-standard premium correction practice needs to be carefully communicated with the policyholders in practice. There are some limitations in the above study that are worth addressing in the future research. Firstly, the two numerical examples given above were based on a number of assumptions, including aggregate claims distribution, claim frequency distribution, transi- tion rules for premium adjustment, number of premium levels and the specific external environment processes. Whether or not these assumptions hold in real practice need to be verified and more appropriate assumptions may be required to improve the model results. Secondly, in real life the parameters associated with the assumptions need to be estimated using real-life data. For instance, we used hypothetical transition probabilities among different environment states in both our numerical examples, but in real life these probabil- ities need to be estimated using real-life economic data or meteorological data. Moreover, if the environment-initiated non-homogeneity does exhibit in the claim experiences, then the claim frequency and claim severity modelling would become more complicated and generally long-term data would be needed to obtain reliable parameter estimates. Another potential future research could be constructing a continuous-time risk model with the same features as the discrete-time model in this paper. Then we could study the impact of the bonus-malus system and the external Markovian environment on the ultimate-time ruin probability. Author Contributions: Conceptualization, D.O. and X.W.; methodology, D.O. and X.W.; numerical analysis, D.O.; writing–original draft preparation, D.O.; writing–review and editing, X.W.; supervi- sion, X.W.; All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript. Funding: Dhiti Osatakul is supported by the Faculty of Business and Economics studentship by The University of Melbourne and the Chulalongkorn University Scholarship. Acknowledgments: The authors are very grateful to the three anonymous reviewers whose construc- tive comments have led to substantial improvements of this paper. Conflicts of Interest: The authors declare no conflict of interest. Risks 2021, 9, 26 21 of 23 Appendix A Proof of Theorem 2. From (3), we have, for u  0, n 2 N , i 2 L and g 2 R, n+1 n o y (u, n + 1) = P (U < 0) L = c , J = g i,g k 1 i 1 k=1 n+1 ¥ ¥ n o = f P (s)P (U < 0) L = c , J = g, S = s å g,m å u k 1 i 1 1 W,g m=0 s=0 k=1 ¥ ¥ = f P (s) å g,m å W,g m=0 s=u+a +1 i,g u+a i,g n+1 r n o + p (g, h) P (s)P (U < 0) L = c , J = h, S = s u 2 å J å W,g k 1 i 1 h=1 s=0 k=1 u+a u+a i,g i,g ¥ r l = P (s) + p (g, h) f t (m, g) P (s) J g,m å S,g å å å i j å W,g s=m s=u+a +1 h=1 j=1 m=0 i,g n+1 n o P (U < 0) L = c , J = h u+a s 2 2 k j i,g k=2 u+a u+a i,g i,g r l = p (g, h) f t (m, g) P (s)y (u + a s, n) J g,m å å å i j å W,g j,h i,g s=m h=1 j=1 m=0 + P (s). å S,g s=u+a +1 i,g Again, since y (u, 1) only measures the probability of ruin of the business within one time i,g period, the verification of the given boundary condition is trivial. Appendix B Proof of Theorem 5. Similar to the proof of Theorem 4, we have, for u  0, n 2 N , i, j 2 L and g, h 2 R, c (u, n + 1, j, h) i,g n o = P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = g u u T j T 1 i 1 u u r ¥ ¥ 0 m = p (g, h ) f P (s) g,m å J å å W,g m=0 s=0 h =1 P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = h , S = s u u T j T 1 i 2 1 u u u+c u+c ¥ r i i 0 m = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) S,g J g,m fi=jg fg=hg å å å å W,g s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 m=0 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c , J = h , S = s u u T j T 1 i 2 1 u u u+c u+c ¥ r i i l 0 m = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) t 0(m, g) S,g J g,m fi=jg fg=hg å å å å W,g å i j 0 0 s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 m=0 j =1 n o P T  n + 1, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h , S = s u u T T 2 2 u j u j 1 ¥ r u+c u+c l i i 0 m = 1 1 P (s) + p (g, h ) f P (s) t 0(m, g) å S,g å J å g,m å å i j fi=jg fg=hg W,g 0 0 m=0 s=m s=u+c +1 h =1 j =1 n o P T  n, L = c , J = h L = c 0 , J = h u+c s u+c s T j T 2 j 2 i i u+c s u+c s i i u+c u+c r l i i 0 m = p (g, h ) f P (s) t 0(m, g)c 0 0(u + c s, n, j, h) g,m å J å å W,g å i j j ,h i 0 s=m 0 h =1 m=0 j =1 + 1 1 P (s). fi=jg fg=hg å S,g s=u+c +1 i Risks 2021, 9, 26 22 of 23 The verification of the boundary condition is trivial. Appendix C The transition matrix among premium levels in Section 6.1. P = [ p (i, j)] C C,g,h (lr)(lr) 2 3 0.5668 0.2332 0 0 0 0.0709 0.0291 0 0 0 0.0709 0.0291 0 0 0 60.2405 0.3263 0.2332 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 7 6 7 6 0 0.2405 0.3263 0.2332 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 7 6 7 0 0 0.2405 0.3263 0.2332 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 0 0 0.0301 0.0408 0.0291 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.2405 0.5595 0 0 0 0.0301 0.0699 0 0 0 0.0301 0.06997 6 7 60.2114 0.0886 0 0 0 0.4581 0.1919 0 0 0 0.0352 0.0148 0 0 0 7 6 7 0.0900 0.1214 0.0886 0 0 0.1950 0.2631 0.1919 0 0 0.0150 0.0202 0.0148 0 0 6 7 6 7 =6 0 0.0900 0.1214 0.0886 0 0 0.1950 0.2631 0.1919 0 0 0.0150 0.0202 0.0148 0 7. 6 7 0 0 0.0900 0.1214 0.0886 0 0 0.1950 0.2631 0.1919 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.0900 0.2100 0 0 0 0.1950 0.4550 0 0 0 0.0150 0.03507 6 7 60.2129 0.0871 0 0 0 0.0355 0.0145 0 0 0 0.4613 0.1887 0 0 0 7 6 7 0.0900 0.1229 0.0871 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 0 0 0.1950 0.2663 0.1887 0 0 6 7 6 7 6 0 0.0900 0.1229 0.0871 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 0 0 0.1950 0.2663 0.1887 0 7 4 5 0 0 0.0900 0.1229 0.0871 0 0 0.0150 0.0205 0.0145 0 0 0.1950 0.2663 0.1887 0 0 0 0.0900 0.2100 0 0 0 0.0150 0.0350 0 0 0 0.1950 0.4550 Appendix D The transition matrix among premium levels in Section 6.2. P = [ p (i, j)] C C,g,h (lr)(lr) 2 3 0.6329 0.1671 0 0 0 0.0791 0.0209 0 0 0 0.0791 0.0209 0 0 0 60.1664 0.4664 0.1671 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 7 6 7 0 0.1664 0.4664 0.1671 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0.1664 0.4664 0.1671 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.0209 0 0 0.0208 0.0583 0.02097 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.1664 0.6336 0 0 0 0.0208 0.0792 0 0 0 0.0208 0.07927 6 7 0.2864 0.0136 0 0 0 0.6206 0.0294 0 0 0 0.0477 0.0023 0 0 0 6 7 6 7 60.1368 0.1496 0.0136 0 0 0.2965 0.3241 0.0294 0 0 0.0228 0.0249 0.0023 0 0 7 6 7 =6 0 0.1368 0.1496 0.0136 0 0 0.2965 0.3241 0.0294 0 0 0.0228 0.0249 0.0023 0 7. 6 7 0 0 0.1368 0.1496 0.0136 0 0 0.2965 0.3241 0.0294 0 0 0.0228 0.0249 0.0023 6 7 6 7 6 0 0 0 0.1368 0.1632 0 0 0 0.2965 0.3535 0 0 0 0.0228 0.02727 6 7 0.1745 0.1255 0 0 0 0.0291 0.0209 0 0 0 0.3780 0.2720 0 0 0 6 7 6 7 0.0285 0.1460 0.1255 0 0 0.0047 0.0243 0.0209 0 0 0.0617 0.3163 0.2720 0 0 6 7 6 7 6 0 0.0285 0.1460 0.1255 0 0 0.0047 0.0243 0.0209 0 0 0.0617 0.3163 0.2720 0 7 4 5 0 0 0.0285 0.1460 0.1255 0 0 0.0047 0.0243 0.0209 0 0 0.0617 0.3163 0.2720 0 0 0 0.0285 0.2715 0 0 0 0.0047 0.0453 0 0 0 0.0617 0.5883 References Afonso, Lourdes B., Alfredo D. Egidio dos Reis, and Howard R. Waters. 2009. Calculating continuous time ruin probabilities for a large portfolio with varying premiums. ASTIN Bulletin 39: 117–36. [CrossRef] Afonso, Lourdes B., Rui M. R. Cardoso, Alfredo D. Egídio dos Reis, and Gracinda R. Guerreiro. 2020. Ruin Probabilities And Capital Requirement for Open Automobile Portfolios With a Bonus-Malus System Based on Claim Counts. Journal of Risk and Insurance 87: 501–22. [CrossRef] Afonso, Lourdes B., Rui M. R. Cardoso, Gracinda R. Guerreiro, and Alfredo D. Egídio dos Reis. 2017. Measuring the impact of a Bonus-Malus system in finite and continuous time ruin probabilities for large portfolios in motor insurance. ASTIN Bulletin 47: 417–35. [CrossRef] Ágoston, Kolos C., and Márton Gyetvai. 2020. Joint optimization of transition rules and the premium scale in a bonus-malus system. ASTIN Bulletin 50: 743–76. [CrossRef] Baione, Fabio, Susanna Levantesi, and Massimiliano Menzietti. 2002. The Development of an Optimal Bonus-Malus System in a Competitive Market. ASTIN Bulletin 32: 159–70. [CrossRef] Cai, Jun, and David M. Dickson. 2004. Ruin probabilities with a Markov chain interest model. Insurance: Mathematics & Economics 35: 513–25. Constantinescu, Corina, Suhang Dai, Weihong Ni, and Zbigniew Palmowski. 2016. Ruin probabilities with dependence on the number of claims within a fixed time window. Risks 4: 17. [CrossRef] Risks 2021, 9, 26 23 of 23 Denuit, Michel, Montserrat Guillen, and Julien Trufin. 2019. Multivariate credibility modelling for usage-based motor insurance pricing with behavioural data. Annals of Actuarial Science 13: 378–99. [CrossRef] De Pril, Nelson. 1979. Optimal Claim Decisions for a Bonus-Malus System: A Continuous Approach. ASTIN Bulletin 10: 215–22. [CrossRef] Dionne, Georges, and Olfa N. Ghali. 2005. The (1992) Bonus-Malus System in Tunisia: An Empirical Evaluation. Journal of Risk and Insurance 72: 609–33. [CrossRef] Dufresne, Par Francois. 1988. Distributions stationnaires d’un système bonus–malus et probabilité de ruine. ASTIN Bulletin 18: 31–46. [CrossRef] Kucer ˇ ovský, Dan, and Amir P. Najafabadi. 2017. Solving an Integral Equation Arising from the Ruin Probability of Long-term Bonus-Malus Systems. Available online: https://arxiv.org/abs/1701.05570 (accessed on 1 September 2020). Lee, Bong-Joo, and Dae-Hwan Kim. 2016. Moral Hazard in Insurance Claiming from a Korean Natural Experiment. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance: Issues and Practice 41: 455–67. [CrossRef] Lemaire, Jean. 1995. Bonus-Malus Systems in Automobile Insurances. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Lemaire, Jean, and Hongmin Zi. 1994. A Comparative Analysis of 30 Bonus-Malus Systems. ASTIN Bulletin 24: 287–309. [CrossRef] Li, Bo, Weihong Ni, and Corina Constantinescu. 2015. Risk models with premiums adjusted to claims number. Insurance: Mathematics & Economics 65: 94–102. Li, Jingchao, and Shuanming Li. 2020. Some State-Specific Exit Probabilities in a Markov-Modulated Risk Model. Mathematical Problems in Engineering 2020: 5830245. [CrossRef] Nie, Changwei, Mi Chen, and Haiyan Liu. 2020. On a Discrete Markov-Modulated Risk Model with Random Premium Income and Delayed Claims. Mathematical Problems in Engineering 2020: 3042543. [CrossRef] Niemiec, Malgorzata. 2007. Bonus-Malus Systems as Markov Set-chains. ASTIN Bulletin 37: 53–65. [CrossRef] Park, Sojung C., Jean Lemaire, and Choong Tze Chua. 2010. Is the design of bonus-malus systems influenced by insurance maturity or national culture? Evidence from Asia. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance: Issues and Practice 35: S7–S27. [CrossRef] Pinquet, Jean, Montserrat Guillén, and Catalina Bolancé. 2001. Allowance for the Age of Claims in Bonus-Malus Systems. ASTIN Bulletin 31: 337–48. [CrossRef] Pitrebois, Sandra, Michel Denuit, and Jean-Francois Walhin. 2006. Multi-Event Bonus-Malus Scales. Journal of Risk and Insurance 73: 517–28. [CrossRef] Trufin, Julien, and Stéphane Loisel. 2013. Ultimate ruin probability in discrete time with Bühlmann credibility premium adjustments. Bulletin Franais d’Actuariat 13: 73–102. Vilar-Zanón, José L., Antonio Heras, and Estela de Frutos. 2020. An average model approach to experience based premium rates discounts: An application to Spanish agricultural insurance. European Actuarial Journal 10: 361–75. [CrossRef] Viswanathan, Krupa, and Jean Lemaire. 2005. Bonus-malus Systems in a Deregulated Environment: Forecasting Market Shares Using Diffusion Models. ASTIN Bulletin 35: 299–319. [CrossRef] Wagner, Christian. 2002. Time in the red in a two state markov model. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 31: 365–72. [CrossRef] Wu, Xueyuan, Mi Chen, Junyi Guo, and Can Jin. 2015. On a discrete-time risk model with claim correlated premiums. Annals of Actuarial Science 9: 322–42. [CrossRef]

Journal

RisksMultidisciplinary Digital Publishing Institute

Published: Jan 14, 2021

There are no references for this article.